Keith Rankin is a political economist and economic historian. |
Profit has a bad name in the leftwing press. It is seen
as the central capitalist vice; as a nomdeplume
for greed.
In reality, profit maximisation is no more symptomatic of moral
decay than is wage maximisation, leisure maximisation, pain minimisation,
crime minimisation. The central concept of economics as a discipline
is that people maximise the things they like and seek to minimise
what they don't like. That's a perfectly sound basis for enquiry
in social science.
Two recent leftwing speakers in Auckland (Immanuel Wallerstein
and Richard Douthwaite [see Immanuel Wallerstein on the Crisis
of the World System and Richard Douthwaite on the
Instability of the Global Marketplace ) left their audiences
in no doubt that profit was a part of the problem of the capitalist
world system.
Wallerstein followed the Marxian premise that capitalism is a
frenetic but ultimately irrational drive to accumulate profits
for their own sake. As a positive feedback process this capitalist
drive may have got humankind out of the equilibrium trap that
was feudalism, but its inherent contradictions are now catching
up with us.
In his basic analytical model, Marx adopts the dubious sociology
of David Ricardo, the founder in the 1810s of classical economic
rationalism. Ricardo saw profits as the driving force of economic
growth, because, he assumed, profits would be invested whereas
income from other funds - such as rent and wages - would be spent
on consumption. For Ricardo and Marx after him, 'profits' imply
'savings'. (The eminent 20th century economist, Paul Samuelson,
while acknowledging Marx's contribution to sociology, called Marx
a "minor postRicardian economist".)
This sociology, the ideas that profit is qualitatively different
from other sources of income and that people who gain a high share
of their income from profit are socially different (ie they are
Scrooges), is central to Marxism, to the A+B theorem of Douglas
Credit, and to the "supplyside trickledown theory"
of new classical economics. (Gerald Scully, consultant to the
New Zealand Inland Revenue Department, can be called a new classical
economist.) Wallerstein even invoked the A+B theorem in his Auckland
lectures, without calling it by that name, when claiming that
only wages feed back into the economy as consumer demand.
For Ricardo and Scully, the claim that capitalists are Scrooges
serves as a reason to channel greater proportions of national
income into their pockets. High profits are the key to economic
growth. For Marx, Major Douglas and Wallerstein, the claim that
capitalists are Scrooges is every reason to limit the flow of
income to capitalists, because it is the mindless accumulation
of capital that destabilises the modern word system.
This is all dogma. There is no rational reason to believe that
"capitalists" have a higher propensity to save the last
dollar they acquire than do wage workers, beneficiaries or governments.
Redistributing income by raising capitalists' profits does not
necessarily lead to a higher rate of savings. And savings are
not the driving force of economic growth.
Profit is two things: it is a cost or it is a surplus. It represents
the income anticipated by the shareholders, the owners. Thus,
as Adam Smith emphasised over 220 years ago, demands by shareholders
for high profits represent significant costs to the firm, just
as demands for high wages represent costs to the firm, and high
income tax rates represent high costs to the firm.
Profit, as a cost, is a market price; the price that governs the
capital market. It is in fact the interest rate, in one of its
guises. As interest rates on bank deposits rise, then shareholders
demand a higher return from the firms they own. Otherwise they
will sell some of their shares and put the money in the bank.
This is the most important and least understood way in which interest
rates act as a production costs. (Thus rising interest rates,
hence rising profit rates, are inflationary, contrary to the assumptions
that underpin the 1989 Reserve Bank Act.)
Public companies - ie companies listed on the stock exchange -
that do not pay competitive dividends will see the value of their
shares fall. The whole sharemarket should fall if interest rates
rise and dividends across the board cannot maintain their traditional
margin over fixed interest returns, but the prospect of speculative
capital gains can counter this pattern. In the 1990s, unlike the
1980s, rising world share prices have generally been driven by
falling interest rates.
Profits as a surplus, represent entrepreneurial income. Narrowly
defined, an entrepreneur is someone selfemployed or incorporated
as a private company (eg a partnership). Entrepreneurs hire labour,
land and capital (factor inputs), they purchase commodity inputs,
and they sell goods and services as outputs. They pay wages, rents,
interest, taxes. And they get to keep what's left, as a surplus,
as a profit. Their profits are their personal incomes, which may
be high, low or negative. Entrepreneurial surpluses should not
be thought of as production costs.
In practice, 'entrepreneurial companies' are often new and undercapitalised.
Under those conditions, surpluses are likely to be ploughed back
into a fledgling company rather than spent on consumer goods.
Entrepreneurial success takes place when the prevailing 'rate
of profit' is low, whereas capitalists like the rate of interest
or profit to be high. A low prevailing rate of interest means
less of an entrepreneur's revenue has to be paid as interest,
or as "profits" to sleeping (rentier) partners.
Some entrepreneurs make high surpluses and have low capital costs.
They also pay few taxes, if they operate in the twilight zone
of the informal or illegal economy. These entrepreneurs, which
include drug dealers and prostitutes, are not well known as congenital
Scrooges. Their profits are simply their incomes, spent in much
the same ways as are other people's incomes. Wage and salary earners
are just as likely to save their earnings as are profiteers.
Richard Douthwaite placed great emphasis on the potential for
locally oriented nonprofit enterprises. His ideas are by
no means new. The Building Society and Cooperative Wholesale Society
movements were built on a nonprofit basis last century.
The claimed virtue of this kind of collective entrepreneurship
is that one layer of cost - the profit layer - is eliminated.
Profits are not really eliminated; rather the profit is distributed
as rebates to customers and is missing from the accounts. Ironically,
by distributing profits to customers, the 'nonprofit' principle
rewards consumers rather than owners. Certainly the neoclassical
economists of the late 19th century and the early 20th century,
who placed great emphasis on "consumer sovereignty",
were not opposed to such 'nonprofit' enterprises.
I favour a system in which all producers are subject to what might
be called "profit accounting". This might seem like
a 'nono' to the left; like requiring schools, universities
and public hospitals to make a profit. I do not believe that profit
accounting acts as the thin end of that wedge; profits would simply
be accounting constructs and not additional costs. But profit
accounting can be the thin end of another wedge. By emphasising
the concept of 'ownership' and the rights of owners as owners,
profit accounting can lead to new perspectives favouring owners
rather than consumers.
Consumption, and not the profit motive, is the real driving force
of modern capitalism. Consumer sovereignty is the main way in
which profits are transferred to those who consume the most (ie
the rich), and is the main reason why capitalism has a bias against
leisure and non-market work as alternative forms of welfare.
How would profit accounting be applied to a publiclyowned
and publiclyfunded school. It would attribute a return to
the owner at the prevailing normal rate of profit, say 10%. There
would be no change in the amount of funds actually paid to the
school. The profit would be an exercise in doubleentry bookkeeping.
The revenue of the school would be raised by 10%, and the payments
would be raised by an equal amount. The profit would be accounted
for as a part of the school's contribution to GDP (gross domestic
product). The profit would be accounted for as an explicit return
to the owner; to the sovereign, to the people.
(We already account for benefits in such a way. Benefits and student
allowances are nominally taxable, enabling a better integration
between the accounting for tax purposes of different components
of persons' incomes. Benefits are always quoted net of tax. The
gross payment exists for accounting purposes only.)
The correct cost of any productive facility, be it a school or
a supermarket, includes a return to its owners. Thus, profit accounting
is one way in which costs are internalised.
An interesting example of profit accounting is the commercialisation
of public utilities. While profit accounting could have been applied
to public utilities such as airports without them being commercialised,
in practice it was commercialisation that forced profit accounting
to be adopted. There have been problems with the commercialisation
process, but not because of profit accounting. Problems occurred
in the main because (i) public utilities are natural monopolies
which mean that their senior employees and consultants are able
to draw off their surpluses, and (ii) they are being set up so
that they can be sold.
In many cases, shares in public utilities have been made transferable,
creating some wonderful opportunities for capitalists. In other
cases, the commercialisation process has worked very well - as
for example, through the role of the Auckland Regional Services
Trust (ARST) when under the management of the Alliance.
Mercury Energy - Auckland's electricity retailer - is not a part
of the ARST. But it does pay explicit dividends to its owners,
whereas before it paid implicit dividends to the biggest users
of electricity. Electricity distribution has moved to a system
of profit accounting. But it has also, through commercialisation,
been able to exploit its monopoly position to extract a bigger
surplus; an amount quite separate to the profit returned as a
cost to its owners. That surplus has effectively become the property
of the executive of Mercury Energy, and not its owners. Public
utilities, as monopolies, should be regulated as well as subject
to profit accounting; regulated to ensure that surpluses are eliminated,
so that electricity prices represent a true reflection of the
costs of electricity retailing.
The ARST, as perceived by the Alliance, is a good example of a
"social profit enterprise". It is socially owned and
pays social dividends; in this case to the greater Auckland community.
These are universal dividends; not handouts to the deserving.
The logical extension of the idea is, of course, that social profit
accounting will apply to the nation as a whole, and also to the
international community of humankind. But it's an idea that can
only work if profits, representing the economic rights of owners,
are acknowledged. The national sovereign - a figurehead for the
people - is the owner of all of the productive resources that
are shared at the national level. The social profit represents
the economic return to the public domain. The people are
entitled to get a return on what they own, whether we are concerned
with that component of profit which represents the cost of maintaining
and enriching the public domain, or that component which represents
an economic surplus.
In any economy, one economic class is able to gain the surplus
income. It should be the public fund, and not the capital or labour
funds (ref. Class: Economic, Social, Political )
that receive the economic surplus. This can only happen when the
economic rights of proprietors - all proprietors - are acknowledged.
Hence the need for explicit profit accounting.
There are a number of difficulties in achieving the goal set out
above. One is that the term 'ownership', like profit, is cemented
in our minds as a very capitalistic term, with all of the negative
connotations for the left that that embodies. There is an offsetting
positive, in that the language is perhaps not offputting
to those people who are not on the political left, but with whom
the left must maintain a dialogue with.
The connotations surrounding the term 'ownership' are changing however. The term now refers less to private chattels over which some persons have exclusive property rights. Rather, 'taking ownership of' something is coming to mean taking responsibility for something, as in the idea that we cannot solve problems unless we 'take ownership' of them. Thus ownership becomes an obligation, and profit becomes a human right deriving from that obligation. The idea was recently expressed by George Salmond, former DirectorGeneral of Health, discussing the present predicament of New Zealand's public health system:
The driving force of capitalism is not the accumulation of profits - as savings - by capitalists. It is the acquisitive drive by consumers for indefinite increases in goods and services; a drive facilitated by our concept of consumer sovereignty. The most successful consumers are capitalists, or salaried people who politically identify with capitalism. They get to consume the social profits that they acquire on account of our failure to properly account for profit.
![]() |