Keith Rankin

Keith Rankin is a political economist and economy historian
who lives in Auckland, New Zealand.
His biographical info.
Keith's email contact is: <keithr@ak.planet.gen.nz>.


The Rankin File

Now go to:

Keith Rankin Keith Rankin

Keith Rankin's site


 Go to   Athens/Delphi: David's Pi_ge
 Go  to   RainForest:  David's  Page :
http://www.oocities.org/RainForest/6783/




The Rankin File: #10



The Case for Higher Taxes and Social Spending.

Thursday, 2 October 1997

"It is time for a national debate on the role of the state in our lives. For a decade politicians have been preaching what they think is best for us. Seldom have they bothered to listen. It is time they did. From one end of the country to the other there is growing disquiet about the repercussions of the Government's retreat from major areas of our lives. The crisis in the education and health systems grows worse by the day, while on the streets the police fight a losing battle to retain staff and defeat crime. Yet in the midst of the mess, Mr Birch hangs doggedly to his promise to lower the tax rate for the wealthy. Part, it seems, of his and Mrs Shipley's 'war on social spending'.... It is time government politicians asked the public whether the price of tax cuts for the wealthy is worth the downstream social costs involved. The widespread public disquiet about the ongoing crises in health, welfare and education suggest not."

The Government has two ways of impacting on our lives: through its executive power to make policy, and through its willingness to provide public goods as part of a social wage. In New Zealand from the 1980s, as Government has retreated from the latter social expenditure role, it has become more prominent as a source of arbitrary power. Hence, the support for MMP as a means of curbing the growing power of a diminishing public goods provider.

MMP has worked, to the disgust of those whose codeword today is more "economic leadership". For "economic leadership", read "tax cuts". In the absence of MMP, we would have had a National Government that was able to implement a commercialist agenda without checks - an agenda of powerful government rather than big government - of government acting in accordance with the dominant business interests. Coalition government, along with a more diverse parliament, has stemmed the commercialist tide just a little; it has checked the return of the "commercial system" that Adam Smith so strongly opposed. The new political environment has seeded doubts about the programme of delivering ongoing dividends to the wealthy, through cuts to income tax.

The public cannot rely, however, on the vigilance of minority coalition partners to expose all future commercialist rorts. New Zealand First has had to indulge the electorate on tax cuts as part of the trade-off for September's superannuation referendum. The expectation remains that there will be a further round of tax cuts in 1999 or 2000, in addition to those already legislated for in 1998. It is no secret that these tax cuts will involve a significant cut to the top (33%) tax rate.

As it is, the 1998 tax cuts give much to the rich and little to those on low incomes. They will give much to those who would have had little to pay under the Compulsory Retirement Savings Scheme. The 1999­2000 cuts will give, proportionately, even more to the rich and even less to the poor. We have to start opposing them now. First, we draw a line in the sand: the 1998 tax cuts will be the last.

In the longer run, social democrats have to remake the case for higher taxes. For me, the tax issue is central to the concept of economic sovereignty; indeed the reassertion of the role of the sovereign as an "agent of production" - as a provider of public goods and as the landlord of the public domain - may be a prerequisite to the turning rather than just the stemming of the commercialist tide.

Income taxes represent one half of the fiscal contract; a contract that is an implicit social contract. A social wage represents the other half. Social democrats - all who are suspicious of the commercialist system of small powerful governments - should be getting behind the social wage concept, and openly acknowledging that a bigger less powerful government needs to levy higher taxes in order to fund a higher social wage.

Taxes represent the revenue of the sovereign. They represent production costs, rents, royalties; charges legitimately levied for the use of public goods and socially­owned property; for everything in our economic universe that is not the subject of a private property right. Thus, taxes are paid - or should be paid - in proportion to the use of public resources. The income taxes that we like to say we pay as individuals are really a share of income generated by our employers, and they rightly represent a proportion of our employers' rather than of our personal use of public domain resources.

Taxes are not a deadweight cost in the economy. Just like any other economic cost - ie just like wages and interest - taxes also represent an income for someone. In particular taxes represent an income to the sovereign. The sovereign can be thought of as a nominal figurehead, with absolute property rights over the public domain, and whose administrative agent is "the Government". But the sovereign is really "the people", treated for analytical convenience as a single party.

We can think of the entire income of the sovereign as the "social wage fund", a fund that is owned equally by every citizen. (For the purpose of economic analysis, the term "citizen" closely matches the term "tax resident" that is currently used by the Inland Revenue Department. The use of this term implies that every human being is a citizen of one and only one country.) Thus, if the NZ social wage fund is equal to $NZ 45 billion, then the social wage attributed to each New Zealander is $12,500, given a national population of 3.6 million.

This approach could be taken up by a far right party such as Libertarianz to justify a Social Dividend of $12,500 per person, no tax increases, and no spending by government on public goods. (Or, more likely, a social dividend of $6,000 plus big tax cuts.) The entire social wage would then become a social dividend, and the stock of social capital would be allowed to erode.

The opposite extreme sees none of the social wage paid as cash to citizens. In that form, the social wage is entirely represented by government spending. That's OK, so long as the spending is mandated on our behalf through the political process. Government spending is social­wage funded, which means that each citizen - including children - contribute equally to the provision of benefits and social services. It is not true to say that the rich - who pay more taxes - pay more for more social expenditure. It is the sovereign who pays more.

The intermediate position places the sovereign in an analogous position to that of a private or public company. Indeed, the sovereign is a corporate representation of the public. All of the income of an incorporated entity is the property of the corporation's shareholders. Some is paid out as equal dividends, and some is ploughed back into the company to maintain and enrich its stock of capital. Retained company profits are analogous to the retention of social wage income by government in order to fund social spending and to invest in social capital.

The intermediate position suggests a balance between social dividends, current social expenditure, and social investment.

We must avoid the following increasingly common style of thinking about taxes; a style of thinking that implies social expenditure should be more favourable to high income recipients:

"Do men or women pay more taxes, on average, and do men or women receive a greater share, on average, of government subsidies and benefits?"

Government expenditure is funded from the income of the sovereign - the social wage fund. It is not funded more by men than by women, by white than by brown, by rich than by poor, by those of working age than by the old and the young. Government expenditure is funded equally be everyone, and should be spent in accordance with social priorities.

Higher taxes mean higher charges to those who make greatest use of public domain resources, and they mean higher incomes to the sovereign. We are entering a fiscal crisis, as the Sunday Star­Times editorial acknowledges; a crisis represented by a lack of social expenditure and by a failure to pay equitable social dividends. Higher taxes are an important part of the solution.

From the point of view of a low wage earner, higher taxes may mean a cut to net wages. But they also mean a higher social wage. For example, for someone today on $20,000 per annum net, a net annual wage cut of $500 resulting from higher taxes might be matched by an increase of $1,000 in that person's social wage. That person's true income would rise from $32,500 ($20,000 + $12,500) to $33,000 ($19,500 + $13,500).

The higher social wage could incorporate a universal benefit as a formal social dividend. Rather than granting tax cuts as a means to pay social dividends to the rich, tax increases make it possible to pay genuine social dividends to all, rich and poor. And they make it possible for the government, accountable to a representative parliament (accountable in part by "airing its dirty washing in public"), to provide the social expenditure that the public demands.

© 1997 Keith Rankin


 Back  to:  Rankin File  Archive
Keith Rankin's Page Go  to  Keith  Rankin's  page

( viewings since 28 Dec.'97: )