The Rankin File: #11



Valuing Unpaid and Underpaid Work.

Monday, 6 October 1997

Economies are characterised by interdependence. That means that what we produce - whether marketed or not - is a result of coordination; of teamwork between the owners of capital and the owners of labour, and between many different workers, paid, unpaid, and underpaid.

Unpaid work is work that does not feature in the national accounts because it is not marketed, but it may nevertheless contribute to a nation's Gross Domestic Product (GDP). Work that is produced and consumed within the household economy (or the voluntary sector) only affects GDP inasmuch as it may involve inputs that are purchased from the market economy. (The work itself can however be said to be a part of a wider measure of production than GDP: "Gross Economic Product".)

Work performed without pay in support of a partner, relative, agent etc. who is producing in the market economy does however contribute to GDP. However, given the structure of the national accounts, the value of that work is attributed to the business of the partner, relative or agent such as a partner's employer or client.

Some such unpaid contributions are acknowledged, though, in the Household Labour Force Survey (HLFS), and in the Census. In both of these, a person who normally works without pay in a "relative's" business for one hour or more per week is classed as employed. (The census specifically excused such persons from answering the question about whether they were looking for work on the grounds that, in the words of one Statistics New Zealand staffer, "we are not interested in whether employed people are searching for work").

Other unpaid contributions - eg working for a school's Board of Trustees - are acknowledged elsewhere in the census, as voluntary work. The "inputs" of the Board of Trustees directly contributes to a school's "outputs", which are measured in the GDP statistics. So does the unpaid overtime put in by school principals and teachers. Principals and teachers, by being partly unpaid, can be said to be underpaid.

Being unpaid and underpaid are part of the same phenomenon. Being unpaid is an extreme form of underpayment. Underpaid workers contributing to the market economy give part or all of the value of their work to others; typically to their employers, or to their employers' employers (eg where they are employed by subcontractors). Unpaid domestic workers - especially mothers (who in many cases are, in addition, paid workers) - produce whole generations to help produce the GDP of the future.

Each new generation claims the private incomes of the future; private incomes made possible in large part by their inheritance of the product of the paid and unpaid work of preceding generations, as well as by their own work, and their partners' often unpaid work.

-----------------------------------

Since the 1991 Employment Contracts Act, underpaid workers have increasingly contributed by accepting less for doing more. They contribute through their product, and not through their taxes. (Exploited workers produce a lot, but it is the exploiters who own and sell what the workers' produce who pay most of the taxes, by virtue of the fact that the employers of exploited labour have much higher incomes than do exploited workers. Exploitation always takes place when a labour market is oversupplied.)

It is only when underpaid and unpaid workers become eligible for a public pension that they get some monetary recognition for what they give up as workers. That is reason enough for any society to pay a public pension. On the other hand, a belief in retirement incomes that are proportionate to workers' paid incomes during their working lives - ie the proceeds of savings or insurance schemes - assumes that individuals' incomes accurately represent their contributions.

When seen in this light, a public pension seems like a pittance; a minimal recognition of the contribution of unpaid and underpaid workers, if that. Even so, public pensions are under threat. Young people today have been conditioned into believing that they may not get any public retirement income.

By an extension of the reasoning that sees a public pension as a reward for all service and not just paid service, it seems appropriate to recognise such contributions for people of working age as well as those of retirement age. Such recognition would mean the paying of a social dividend if not a full universal basic income (UBI). A social dividend, which can be constructed at little cost from existing tax concessions, can be important as a recognition, within the public accounting framework, of our unpaid and underpaid contributions. A public pension could then be seen as an additional recognition; a long service bonus.

In an interdependent world, it is virtually impossible to assess every person's individual contribution to the economic wellbeing of the nation, let alone to the wellbeing of the planet. So a universal means of attributing value to contributions is appropriate; a means that errs in favour of the proposition that everyone makes a contribution, or at least wishes to.

The bureaucratic cost of punishing the few who do not make any public contribution (or who are deemed not to make any contribution) is just not worth it. The withholding of entitlements should not be used as a form of punishing people thought by some to be lacking a work ethic. Work is not the only form of contribution, and nor has it ever been the only basis for a person receiving a paid income.

We need to modify our public accounts so as to give explicit recognition of unpaid and underpaid contributions to GDP. Our social wage should include a social dividend and a public pension.

© 1997 Keith Rankin


 Back  to:  Rankin File  Archive
Keith Rankin's Page Go  to  Keith  Rankin's  page

( viewings since 28 Dec.'97: )