The Rankin File: #2



Contrasting Views of the International Economy

Monday, 15 September 1997
"One of the things that makes me slightly nervous about the use of the globe as an image these days is that if I look through all the art historical images of globes, whether it is queens or kings or navigators, or scientists, to people who are leaning on the globe or measuring the globe or make some sort of statement about their empire, I've never once seen an image of someone having a globe in their hands and giving it away. It is an act of taking in, and one of the things that worries me is we use words like global, like international, but we are using those words because we cannot use the word imperial any more."

There are three distinct perspectives on the international economy. I'll call them 'nationalist', 'cosmopolitan', and 'ultra­imperialist', more or less in line with the themes of Bernard Semmel's 1993 book, The Liberal Ideal and the Demons of Empire.

There are nationalist, cosmopolitan and ultra­imperialist arguments for free trade. The classical view of free trade - dating back to Adam Smith - was inherently nationalist. The mid­twentieth neoclassical and Keynesian views are cosmopolitan, and the contemporary neoliberal view is ultra­imperialist.

Adam Smith mooted free trade as a superior form of pursuing national economic interests (morally superior and a more efficient use of national resources) to those of the 'mercantilists' whom Smith identified with "the commercial system". The commercial system - the orthodoxy of the seventeenth and eighteenth centuries, especially in England - was an advocacy of national development through export­led growth (especially the export of manufactures); a political economy characterised by strong leadership on the part of government to further the interest of the merchant capitalists.

Mercantilism was a system in which the sovereign and the capitalists lined each others pockets. In promoting an export surplus - reflecting a belief that a nation's wealth was measured by its monetary reserves - mercantilism favoured import protection as a complement to export incentives. Thus mercantilism came in the twentieth century to be equated to 'protectionism', 'interventionism', 'Muldoonism'; even 'self­sufficiency' in the minds of some with a poor grasp of history.

Mercantilist policies - called "leadership" by those who stood to benefit from them - overemphasised trade. Where implemented, they served as a recognition that private capital had usurped a significant degree of 'economic sovereignty' over a whole nation.

Whereas economic sovereignty traditionally exists at a national level - as it did in Smith's time, and as it did throughout the years of the "Pax Britannica" of the nineteenth century and the "Pax Americana" of the mid­twentieth century - it also exists at an international level.

Cosmopolitan political economy exists where the economic relations between nations and the citizens of different nations are regulated by liberal means to maximise the wellbeing of humankind. A cosmopolitan sovereign acts in the international public interest, to further the economic interests of all humankind.

On the other hand, ultra­imperialism is the international equivalent of national merchant capitalism, whereby international capital exerts a de facto sovereignty over the whole globe as a means of furthering its particular interests. This usurpation of sovereignty occurs through pressures to align international institutions with the interests of international capital; just as under the commercial system that Smith described, the national sovereign promotes the interests of national merchant capital. "What's good for General Motors is good for America" becomes accepted as a global proposition.

Ultra­imperialism exists because there is a vacuum in international sovereignty. When there are too few institutions accountable to the international public, the international marketplace - the international markets for goods and services, the international capital market, and the international labour market - becomes the main regulator and the main disciplinarian.

One key symptom of ultra­imperialism is the way national governments compete against each other to win the favours of international capital, in particular by pursuing policies that minimise the costs - taxes and wages - incurred by transnational business, while raising the price (interest rates) of the factor of production (capital) that represents the return to private wealth.

While classical mercantilism and ultra­imperialism have much in common, cosmopolitan political economy is distinctly anti­mercantilist. The way forward is to find a cosmopolitan understanding of and solution to the problems of the international economy. Free trade between fraternal nations is not proving to be the answer- as it was believed it would be in the decolonising era of the 1950s - because the benefits only occur in an environment of global full employment and economic growth.

It is only through 'green' economics that the intuitive approach is both cosmopolitan and protectionist; fair trade rather than free trade between the peoples of the world. If there can be nationalist, cosmopolitan, and ultra­imperialist forms of free trade, then there can also be non­nationalist forms of protected, politically regulated, managed trade.

Just as national markets fail - as any reputable economics textbook will explain - so international markets fail. And the ultra­national markets of contemporary globalisation fail too.

It is the economic role of the sovereign to correct market failure, and to provide public goods. It is not the role of sovereign governments to provide leadership of a form that is detrimental to outsider interests. Appropriate - ie cosmopolitan - protectionism is any form of intervention on the part of any legitimate publicly accountable sovereign power that helps to redress international market failure and to provide international public goods. And that does so without pushing the world economy onto an unsustainable growth path.

A suitable metaphor for economic protection should be a warm blanket and not a nationalist iron curtain. Protection can be a cosmopolitan counterposition to the ultra-imperialist jungle described by Vandana Shiva:

"I think that one of the things we are going to see in a globalised world order is Third World situations emerging in the heart of the industrialised world. Situations disappear, [such] as the assumption of everyone having the right to work; and, [where] they don't have work, having the right to be protected as if they had work. All those assumptions are under very serious attack."

© 1997 Keith Rankin


 Back  to:  Rankin File  Archive
Keith Rankin's Page Go  to  Keith  Rankin's  page

( viewings since 28 Dec.'97: )