"Economists explain the behaviour ... as rent-seeking - the redirection of existing income streams towards themselves rather than the creation of new streams."
Last month (see The Balance of Payments Deficit;
Oct 7), I commented on the large and increasing balance of payments
deficit, and its main cause; a net inflow of foreign capital required
to push the exchange rate up sufficiently to keep inflation below
2 or 3 percent.
A high inflow of capital creates an ongoing revenue outflow which
we call "invisible" payments. The balance on invisibles
is the return to international investment. For New Zealand, it
is the difference between the earnings of foreign interests in
New Zealand and the foreign earnings of New Zealand interests.
Basically, a deficit on invisibles represents the flow of "interest"
- broadly defined - to foreigners.
A large and growing deficit on invisibles is symptomatic of flows
of interest, derived from national "land" (defined very
broadly to mean fixed productive assets) and labour, to international
capital. International capital represents mobile assets held by
parties with no sense of local or national loyalty.
Such a deficit is a problem when the investment that generates the "revenue" stream to international capital is parasitic rather than creative in its nature. A creative investment generates new revenues, and all parties involved can be winners. A parasitic investment however is an appropriation of a resource by an "investor" that does little more than divert an existing revenue stream to that investor. It matters little whether a parasitic investor profiting from New Zealand resources is resident or not.
It is a nation's invisibles - in particular the relationship of invisibles to gross national product (GNP) - that serves as the best available measure of parasitic flows of interest from national resources to international capital. Where foreign investments are on balance creative, rather than parasitic, a nation's GNP rises more than invisible payments.
When there is a deficit on invisibles, GNP, which represents the income of the nation's residents, is less than the gross domestic product (GDP), which represents the product of a nation's resources. Thus, New Zealand's GNP is less than its GDP, by the amount of the invisibles' deficit. Typically, a country receiving inflows of foreign capital will find that its GNP grows less quickly than its GDP. GNP is the more important indicator, inasmuch as either are indicators of national economic well-being.
Brian Gaynor is perhaps the most astute commentator in the New
Zealand business press. On 18 October he published the following
table (Table 1), detailing the subcomponents of New Zealand's
invisibles' balance.
Direct investment in New Zealand is the purchase by foreign interests
of New Zealand companies or shares in New Zealand companies, or
the setting up of new foreignowned companies.
Portfolio investment by foreign interests is, in essence, the
purchase of bonds and other fixedinterest financial assets.
Investment in Government bonds is a form of portfolio investment.
New Zealand bonds become more attractive to foreign investors
either when New Zealand interest rates are high or expected to
fall. Foreign purchasers of New Zealand bonds are looking for
speculative gains from exchange rate appreciation, for capital
gains on bond prices, and for high interest payments. The Reserve
Bank manages inflation by acting to increase portfolio investment
inflows, thereby pushing up the exchange rate.
The first thing to note from Table 1 is that the deficit on invisibles
is larger than the total current account deficit, which means
that New Zealand as a nation actually earns a small surplus on
commodity trade, despite being well short of paying its collective
bills.
The second thing to note is that the majority of foreign profits
and interest are repatriated; suggesting parasitic tendencies.
The third thing to note is that New Zealand investments overseas
actually aggravate rather than ameliorate the invisibles deficit,
thanks to high borrowing from overseas to fund nonperforming
overseas investments.
Gaynor believes that one of the major problems New Zealand faces
is this awful failure of New Zealand investments overseas. I am
sure he is right. But few of these investments are made with the
national interest in mind, and we should not expect too much from
them. They have been a drain on New Zealand's resources; a drain
that has caused New Zealand interest rates to be higher than they
otherwise would have been. They mainly represent capital outflows
similar to those out of Western Ireland described by Richard Douthwaite
(on the Instability of the Global Marketplace),
and the returns (if any) on those investments tend to be held
within the international financial system, and not returned to
the local or national economies which made these investments possible.
The invisibles balance of minus $7.5 billion is funded by exports
of $1.5 billion and additional foreign capital inflows of $6 billion.
Thus, the invisibles deficit will be greater next year, because
the additional $6 billion will add something like $500 million
of foreign investment income next year's deficit. If the $NZ dollar
falls further, then the invisibles deficit will be funded mainly
by more exports and fewer imports. But if the $NZ begins a sustained
rise - and the coming to power of Jenny Shipley as Prime Minister
seems to have caused it to rise - then the 1998 invisibles deficit
will be funded, once again, by increased capital inflows which
will in turn aggravate the invisibles deficit in 1999.
One way that the future problem might be eased is if foreign investments
in New Zealand start to perform as badly as New Zealand investments
overseas do. If there is a major sell off of foreignheld
assets - eg a selloff to shore up an overseas sharemarket
crash - then the prices of those assets will fall and New Zealand
interests may secure windfall gains. It is possible that the problem
will eventually resolve itself with most of the losses incurred
by foreign rather than national interests. In any process of large
scale capital flight from New Zealand, the main losers will prove
to be the international interests doing the fleeing. After all,
most of their assets in New Zealand are denominated in NZ currency,
and capital flight will see a fall in the value of the currency.
New Zealand's present balance of payments problems are not new.
They were worse in the 1880s. However, in the 19th century, exchange
rates were fixed and British sentiment had moved against New Zealand
and in favour of Victoria and Argentina. Thus, there was little
that New Zealand politicians could do other than oversee a rapid
adjustment from an import surplus to an export surplus. New Zealand
had to service its overseas liabilities from export revenue, and
not, as it does today, through increasing its overseas liabilities.
One man who understood the situation very well was Frederick Joseph
Moss, MP for Parnell in the 1880s and British Resident in the
Cook Islands in the 1890s. Table 2 presents his views; views that
can be applied with little modification to the understanding of
our national plight today.
Table 2: | Frederick Joseph Moss (1829-1904) |
One New Zealander who understood the relationship
between exports and imports was Frederick Joseph Moss, MP for
Parnell (187790) and author of Notes on Political
Economy by a New Zealand Colonist (1897). Moss would probably
have been Minister of Finance in the 189093 Liberal Government,
had he not decided early in 1890 to retire from Parliament to
become British Resident in the Cook Islands. Nevertheless, the
reforms of that government followed Moss's economic philosophy,
and Moss's book was an attempt to market our reforms to the British.
On capital imports (export of debentures) funding an excess of imported goods and services, Moss states (my italics): Moss understood that new countries would incur debt and import more while they were investing in infrastructure. And he understood that mature countries that had invested in foreign infrastructure would gain net inflows of investment income, enabling them to import more goods than they exported. Countries with past debts or with a high level of overseas ownership of their assets would suffer a chronic drain on their living standards, as those debts were serviced or repaid: Moss recognised that much of the first "Think Big" borrowing (in the 1870s) did not have to come from overseas, and that it fuelled imports of goods that could in many cases have been made in New Zealand. But he also understood that in the following period (the 1880s), when it became difficult to attract further capital imports, New Zealand had to service its debts through its exports. New Zealand was forced to broaden its economic base. In Parliament he stated: Moss has a very specific message for us today: do not sell Electricorp/Transpower: |
{ This document is: http://www.oocities.org/Athens/Delphi/3142/krf27-invisibl.html.html
{ the above references are to: http://www.oocities.org/Athens/Delphi/3142/krf12-bop_def.html
{ and: http://www.oocities.org/Athens/Delphi/3142/krf21-douthw.html
![]() |
![]() |
( viewings since 28 Dec.'97: )