Keith Rankin

Keith Rankin is a political economist and economy historian
who lives in Auckland, New Zealand.
His biographical info.
Keith's email contact is: <keithr@ak.planet.gen.nz>.


The Rankin File

Now go to:

Keith Rankin Keith Rankin

Keith Rankin's site


 Go to   Athens/Delphi: David's Pi_ge
 Go  to   RainForest:  David's  Page :
http://www.oocities.org/RainForest/6783/




The Rankin File: #30



Competitiveness Buffs are the Real
Merchants of Doom.

Monday 17 November 1997

People who criticise the "Economic Reforms" tend to be portrayed as congenital pessimists and doomsayers. The real merchants of doom are in fact the merchants of business - the "mercantilists" as they are known in economics - who see the world as made up of winners and losers and who are forever telling politicians that the only way for their nation to avoid being a loser is to follow their policy prescriptions.

Economic liberalism emerged gradually in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries as a cosmopolitan worldview which sought "win­win" outcomes from economic exchange: win­win between individuals and win­win between nations. The most prominent nineteenth century economic liberal was John Stuart Mill, who recognised that properly constituted governments played a crucial role in generating win­win outcomes. "Market competition" - to a liberal like Mill - is a form of cooperation; it is a bargaining mechanism that coordinates resources so as to facilitate genuine win­win outcomes.

An earlier manual of liberalism was Adam Smith's Theory of Moral Sentiments, published in 1759, and still a classic text, though little known by economists. (Smith's later book, The Wealth of Nations, was by comparison a nationalist text.) The contrary world view to that of Smith's liberalism was Sir James Steuart's 1767 Principles of Political Œconomy, the most complete statement of mercantilism. (A useful sympathetic account of Steuart's vision of national competitiveness can be found in: Robert Urquhart (1996) "The Trade Wind, the Statesman, and the System of Commerce: Sir James Steuart's vision of political economy", The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought, 3(3):379-410.)

The anti­liberal mercantilist philosophy has been the dominant economic philosophy of England for over 500 years: from the reign of Henry VII to that of John Major. (Tony Blair's economic philosophy is certainly less mercantilist and more liberal than that of John Major, but it is too early to label Blair as a genuine economic liberal.) Mercantilism is "win­lose" economics; it is the economics of "rivalry", of "zero­sum" games, of nationalism. Mercantilism is practiced widely by many politicians and business interests who are convinced that they are promoting economic liberalism. Furthermore, economists employed by those interests tend to turn a blind eye to the distinction between mercantilism and liberalism. Either that, or their education is so lacking in the conceptual aspects of their discipline that they also share the same mercantilist view without realising that it is contrary to liberalism.

Major gave a very clear statement of contemporary mercantilism in a Panorama interview in 1995:

"We are dealing with competitiveness in a world that is changing; we aren't living in the world of the 1960s and the 1970s and even much of the 1980s. Unless we compete and beat the French and the Germans and the Japanese, the Pacific Basin Countries, the United States, we will have huge unemployment, structural unemployment, and dramatically falling living standards." Other British conservatives expressed similar views in the BBC's "State of the World Forum" Debate on the Arms Trade (screened in New Zealand on TV1 early on 15/11/97):

"My responsibility is to the people of this country, and to their welfare and prosperity. I'm not particularly bothered about who we are trading with, so long as we get paid."

"It has often been in the case in the past that if one country is taking a fairly high moral stance, their competitors would take that as a wonderful opportunity to get out and sell."

For a proper perspective on liberalism, there is no­one better to turn to than Deirdre McCloskey (formerly Donald McCloskey; see 1997 article by Livia Polanyi, "Interview With Deirdre McCloskey," Challenge 40:16-29). A strong candidate to being the first woman to win the Nobel Prize in Economics, McCloskey spoke to an enthralled audience in Auckland in July last year, at an international conference on "Narrative and Metaphor across the Disciplines". Having made her initial reputation as a conservative Chicago School economic historian, she is now better known as the pioneer of the branch of economic philosophy known as "The Rhetoric of Economics". She has a regular column in The Eastern Economic Journal that is well worth reading.

McCloskey takes her inspiration from Adam Smith's Theory of Moral Sentiments. As such, she emphasises the concepts of "socialisation" and "socialised self­interest". To act out of socialised self­interest is to take a collective view of individual self­interest. We vote in elections, for example, because we believe that democracy is in our individual self­interest, and not because we think that our particular vote will make any difference to the result.

McCloskey contrasts socialised self­interest with the alternative "Hobbesian" form of self­interest which assumes that individuals act in a short­sighted calculating way (following from Thomas Hobbes' seventeenth century political philosophy as expressed in his book Leviathan), lacking any moral basis. Hobbes is thus seen as the founder of the "economic man" axiomatic to most economic theorising. Under socialised self­interest, we, as individuals, choose to not drink and drive because we understand the social cost of drinking and driving. Under Hobbesian self­interest, any of us may choose to drink and drive without care as to the social consequences. But those of us who would like to drink and drive may choose to not do so if they calculate that the likelihood of getting caught is too high or that the consequences of getting caught are likely to be too costly. A Hobbesian world is economically inefficient because it is populated with cheats, and therefore requires agents (public servants) to impose negative consequences upon cheats. Voluntary compliance, based on socialised self­interest, would enable us to do without those agents.

The mercantilist thinking above by Major, Clark and Levine, represents an unsocialised understanding of a nation's self­interest. Hobbes's "economic man" becomes Steuart's "economic nation". The perception of Clark and Levine is that the British nation will be made better off by being more competitive as an exporter of armaments than Britain's rivals, regardless of the bigger point that global society is itself compromised by the international arms market. The perspective assumes that Britain's rivals take an equally amoral view of the international economy, and that, if Britain did take the moral high ground, then Britain's rivals would somehow gain at Britain's expense, by exporting more weapons. Thus the rivals would be the winners, and Britain the loser.

Real economic nationalism - mercantilism - is based on a view that there is an economic war on out there, and that national self interest is to win that war. The arms trade is a classic example of economic war; of the "prisoners dilemma" problem, whereby competing Hobbesian nations actually produce a "lose­lose" outcome rather than the "win­lose" world supposed by mercantilism.

On the other hand, the prisoners dilemma theorem shows that an international community of socialised nations produces "win­win" outcomes. This alternative view - that of a socialised international community of nations - is that international trade is a means of cooperative resource allocation conducted without the visible hand of a global bureaucracy. If conducted within a properly­defined international public domain, and with appropriate mechanisms to stabilise investment, migration and trade flows, then the international economy becomes the exact opposite of a sporting contest between rival nations. (Deirdre McCloskey holds that this metaphor of economic competition as being like a sports contest is perhaps the most dangerous fallacy held by today's "macho" economics profession.) Socialised self­interest on the part of national governments would be to pursue actions on a moral basis; actions, that if followed by each country's government, would yield the best outcome for all. The McCloskey perspective prescribes unilateral action by each national government that is consistent with the general interest of all nations.

John Major, in expressing the world view of an unsocialised political leader, acts as a prophet of doom. Defeating the French, the Germans, the Japanese, the Pacific Basin Countries and the United States in economic warfare is a big ask!

New Zealand, like Britain, is not short of doom merchants pushing unsocialised economic nationalism. Two good examples appeared in Ian Templeton's column "Political platitudes as expected" in the Sunday Star­Times of 2 November. Expressing the view of the National Bank's Economics Department, he says:

"The National Bank, in its monthly survey, reported business confidence is still rising. ... The bank's economists, however, detected an Achilles Heel: 'alarming' expenditure pressure on an already lavish fiscal programme. 'If a precarious fiscal position were to sow seeds of doubt about the wisdom of next year's tax cuts, or if the tax cuts were to proceed regardless and tip the government's books into the red, the notoriously animalistic spirits of business could quickly sour'."
Here the National Bank argues that businesses are driven by sentiment, and that business sentiment will lead us to disaster unless our government does everything it can to pander to that sentiment. In this case business sentiment is said to include sufficient cuts in public expenditure to ensure both tax cuts and a budget surplus. Tax cuts are seen as a means to gain a competitive edge over rival nations. These kinds of views, repeated in each nation, are really attempts to blackmail each sovereign government into making organised business interests the winners of a global sporting contest. Templeton continues:

"In the global market, New Zealand gets to travel in the back of the bus. ... The question - if New Zealanders want better seats on the bus - is how to sharpen incentives and competitiveness."
This is a wonderfully simple presentation of the illiberal zero­sum world view. Winning means getting "better seats on the bus" by making sure that others get worse seats. The world economy is seen as a destructive contest that will bring doom to the losers. The prisoners dilemma theorem suggests that if all nations are trying to get to the front of the bus, then they will all end up at the back. McCloskey suggests, however, that New Zealanders don't want better seats on the bus. Rather, they want a better bus; they want to contribute more rather than to take more.

An interesting quote on today's XTRA's Internet news page says: "Tau Henare says we still have a government, and the country is not going to go to the pack [emphasis added] because New Zealand First hasn't made a decision." The prophets of doom present the ideology that our country - indeed, any country - is inevitably "going to the pack" (or, using Templeton's metaphor, "going to the back") unless overtly pro­capital policies are pursued. Politicians are forced onto the defensive, because of the political blackmail by the real prophets of doom.

Another Hobbesian economic nationalist with a penchant for political manipulation is former Chairman of the Business Roundtable, Doug Myers. In a feature by Carroll du Chateau in the Sunday Star­Times (16 November), he says:

"New Zealanders want the world's best health service but refuse to recognise that the funds needed to provide it can only come from a competitive [emphasis added] world class business sector. If you want that then someone has to work very hard to make it possible."
What we and all other nations need is a productive rather than a competitive business sector. Real average incomes in the world are around 10 times higher than they were 200 years ago. But people do not work 10 times harder today. It is not hard work that makes us productive, but shared capital which has accumulated as a social inheritance. The use of the term "competitive" instead of "productive" leads easily to this error of reasoning. If we work harder we just make bigger surpluses for organised business, while suffering a wage cut. Furthermore, we don't actually want a better health system than, say, Canada or Australia. We just want a better health system tomorrow than what we have today. Myers' choice of words simply reflects the nationalist perspective that underlies the lobbying style of organised business. He says "with a smile", about the electoral system which he strongly opposes:

"'We voted for [MMP]. It's democracy in action.... We've now got to battle a political system not designed for ease of leadership.... The role of the political leader is out in front, spelling out the vision, sharing the pain and uncertainty and so making the outcome more certain'."
Myers here presents a near perfect example of Sir James Steuart's metaphor of economic nationalism: that of the political leader as a Chris Dickson or a Grant Dalton navigating the Southern Ocean, as per the metaphor of "The Trade Wind, the Statesman, and the System of Commerce". Steuart's vision, for all its merits, is not a liberal vision. The liberal vision is that vision of the Scottish Enlightenment, contemporaneous of Steuart, based on the "moral sentiments". The most effective proponent of that worldview today is Deirdre McCloskey.

By taking McCloskey's "socialised approach" to self­interest, nations, through their governments, can ensure that capital and other interests can all be winners. As nations, we protect our futures by unilaterally doing what is right, and not what seems expedient. A sense of morality is a prerequisite to the achievement of efficient economic outcomes.

© 1997 Keith Rankin

{ This document is:              http://www.oocities.org/Athens/Delphi/3142/krf30-doom_busin.html


 Back  to:  Rankin File  Archive
Keith Rankin's Page Go  to  Keith  Rankin's  page

( viewings since 28 Dec.'97: )