Keith Rankin

Keith Rankin is a political economist and economy historian
who lives in Auckland, New Zealand.
His biographical info.
Keith's email contact is: <keithr@ak.planet.gen.nz>.


The Rankin File

Now go to:

Keith Rankin Keith Rankin

Keith Rankin's site


 Go to   Athens/Delphi: David's Pi_ge
 Go  to   RainForest:  David's  Page :
http://www.oocities.org/RainForest/6783/




The Rankin File: #31



Treading Lightly on our Planet.

Thursday 20 November 1997

"Those who are doomed to spend their day in Queen St. have to endure their sentence under most difficult circumstances. The Auckland dust blend may be regarded as famous in the city, but outsiders stigmatise it as infamous. Large columns of this abominable compost are whirled up into the air and driven along the street. The choked and half­blind pedestrians have to flee into open shops to escape the fury of the blizzard. The watering is insufficient to keep down the destroyer and the side paths are covered with dust so that neither comfort, health nor happiness can be experienced in this thoroughfare."

100 years ago, Auckland appears to have had a problem somewhat worse than the motorway gridlock of today. We can hardly imagine how awful Auckland might be like today if the population had multiplied in the absence of environmental improvements. Indeed, given the serious environmental problems, we might expect Aucklanders living at that time to have been fearful of population growth.

In the late 19th century, as noted by Rollo Arnold (in New Zealand's Burning: the Settlers' World in the mid 1880s, 1994), New Zealand was burning in a rather more extravagant form of environmental vandalism than that currently taking place in Borneo and Sumatra. The worst damage to indigenous fauna, flora and habitats seems to have been related to human settlement, per se, rather than to high or growing populations. Thus it was related to ignorance, and to values more conducive to exploitation than to conservation.

In recent years, one of the world's most highly populated countries, Netherlands, has been restoring former wetlands to their natural state. The Great Lakes of America have been cleaned up. London hasn't had pea­souper fogs since the 1950s. Since "Think Big" in the early 1980s, it has been possible to fish alongside the outflow from the Marsden Point Oil Refinery, and to transport goods from Palmerston North to Hamilton at night using off­peak hydro­electricity generation capacity.

While the world's populations and economies have grown rapidly in the last 50 years, humankind has been learning to tread more lightly on our planet. Although we still have a very long way to go to redress all of the environmental problems of the past, population growth, per se, has not been the principal source of damage to our global habitat. And population growth in the more developed pan­European nations cannot be isolated as having caused more damage than it has cured.

Last week, the government's population conference was held. It was a political conference, in that it represented an acknowledgment of the NZ First Party's anti­immigration campaign in 1996. Media reports suggest that little was achieved by what turned out to be an "unfocused" conference; a conference which seems to have had little to say about the major issues relating to the impact of population growth on the environment. The impact of demographic change on employment seems to have taken priority over the impact on the environment. The Coalition Government is very much a "work ethic" government; a labourist government.

As part of the preamble to the population conference, Simon Collins wrote an interesting article on population and sustainability in his regular Wednesday Herald column (12 November). The key theme of his article was that of "carrying capacity", meaning "optimal sustainable population". Apparently New Zealanders, on average, use resources equivalent to five hectares of productive land; that equates to our population being at 90% of New Zealand's carrying capacity. Collins suggests that the world is populated in excess of its carrying capacity, and that it is therefore not possible for all of the world's population to live at western levels of comfort.

My main criticism of the article is that it leaves the reader with the impression that a higher New Zealand population in the future will continue to use the equivalent of five hectares of productive land per person. Furthermore, the general impression is that Collins is following a "physiocratic" paradigm. Physiocracy means the rule of nature; "land" is regarded as the only true source of economic value. (The Physiocrats - the eighteenth century followers of a French doctor, François Quesnay - were the first sect of economists. They gave us the terms "economist" and "laissez­faire", and they believed that all wealth is ultimately the product of the soil, thereby making the carrying capacity of the soil and the population size as the key determinants of living standards.) Marxism is a direct contrast with physiocracy, in that it attributes all value to labour.

Collins does recognise, however, that carrying capacity and population size are not the only determinants of average world living standards. He notes that we should "put less strain on the environment - by walking, biking and using public transport more, so that we use cars less, for example". The key concept here is what I will call "lightness of tread". Treading lightly does not mean reduced living standards, but it does mean that each person consumes much less than 5ha of resources. We can raise our carrying capacity if we tread more lightly. What interests me is the converse proposition; to what extent can population growth cause us to tread less obtrusively?

The usual assumption is that carrying capacity is fixed: each European or American treads more heavily than each Asian or African, implying that an additional New Zealander will be more damaging to the world than an additional Bangladeshi. We should however consider "carrying capacity" and "lightness of tread" as key economic variables; not as economic constants. The question to ask is what happens to these variables "at the economic margin" as population increases? How many additional resources do additional people consume? Can additional people actually lead to reduced environmental depreciation? If so, under what conditions can the effective marginal weight of tread be less than zero?

We can take three perspectives on the problem: (i) short­term "partial equilibrium", (ii) scale­economy "general equilibrium", and (iii) a historical perspective that allows for changing technology, knowledge and values. ("Values" tend to be called "tastes" in neoclassical economics.)

In the first perspective, we make the assumptions implicit in Collins' article, except one. Because most of the resources we use are tied to our infrastructure (which is fixed in the short term), an addition of population of one person makes no additional demands on infrastructure. If the extra person has a typical kiwi lifestyle, the total use of resources will rise, but the average use of resources will fall. In practice, this might translate into a one­off population increase of 2% leading to an increased resource usage of 1%.

To the extent that additional infrastructure is required - eg if that 2% increase is an annual average and not a one­off - then new knowledge and techniques mean that the resource cost of the extra infrastructure should be less than that associated with past infrastructure. So "treading lightly" means, in part, the adoption of infrastructures that have a high "productivity of land". And it means that new environmentally sensitive infrastructure replaces old infrastructure, creating intra­marginal efficiency gains; ie reducing the resource cost of everyone, and not just the additional person.

When economists talk about productivity, they usually mean "productivity of labour", but increasingly they have come to mean "total factor productivity", where high productivity implies treading lightly with respect to nature, and treading lightly with respect to infrastructure, meaning that the construction of new infrastructure can often be delayed. Total factor productivity means economising on land and on capital (eg infrastructure), as well as economising on labour. One important form of treading lightly is to promote economic growth in (and hence population inflow into) regions with underutilised infrastructure. Thus, by following an active regional employment policy, we can raise the carrying capacity of our infrastructure, and therefore can devote less land to infrastructure.

Switching to a "scale­economy general equilibrium" point of view, we might imagine a sudden population influx. In a thought experiment we might simply double the NZ population, and imagine how the New Zealand economy would adjust. We could no more assume that the population would continue to use five hectares of resources each than we could imagine a doubling of Auckland's population in 1897 without some adjustments to land use. Economies of scale can mean significant efficiency gains. The obvious example is the one that Collins raises; namely public transport. An Auckland with two million people would have to have a decent public transport system, and might even have less private traffic than an Auckland of one million.

I have recently been to Vienna, a city of 1.7 million inhabitants. It has a brilliant public transport system, including a busy underground railway, a well­patronised tram system, and much less traffic than Auckland. Living standards in Austria are 50% higher than in New Zealand. New Zealand cities had tram systems once, but lost them in large part because population growth was too slow to sustain them. Austrians live better than New Zealanders, while treading more lightly.

The historical perspective factors in changes in technology and changes in our values. As a population grows, and experiences economic growth, it not only chooses new techniques on account of changing scale, but it can facilitate the development of new techniques; techniques that help whole populations to tread the planet more lightly, despite greater numbers.

New techniques are made possible by changing values as well as new knowledge. A high and growing population values its scarce natural resources much more than does a low, static or stressed population. Economically static populations may draw down their natural capital more slowly than growing populations, but the historical record shows that they did draw down their natural capital, creating subsistence crises on account of their populations' inability to adapt.

It is dynamic populations whose values evolve. Thus it is quite possible for a growing population to tread more lightly as it grows. The industrial revolution has raised the carrying capacity of the earth even more dramatically than it has raised the world's population. Thus it has constituted a 150 year long learning curve that has given us the capability of treading lightly in post­industrial comfort.

Being able to tread lightly does not however mean that humankind will tread lightly. Human society continues to contain directly conflicting values. A sustainable future depends very much on which value system prevails, and it depends very little on numbers, per se. For those with little concern for the future, the present control over and exploitation of valuable natural resources represents a means to the achievement of very high surplus profits.

Just as rising populations can generate dynamic change conducive to increased sustainable carrying capacity, it is quite possible for a falling world population to coincide with or even to generate terrible environmental crises. A world of growing inequality does lead to rising death rates, and to intense competition for artificially limited resources. Stressed populations care only about today, not tomorrow, and have no incentive to conserve, to tread lightly. Many of the worst environmental abuses this century have been perpetrated by the stressed populations of the Third World, be it deforestation in Amazonia, Africa, Indonesia or upriver from Bangladesh. The biggest energy crisis on the planet is that of a high demand for scarce firewood. There are already a number of practical technical solutions to these problems, but a lack of political will combined with the intense conservatism of culturally static agrarian communities makes adaptation very difficult.

Of course, there are limits to population growth. Fortunately, a society with a value system that facilitates lightness of tread also facilitates other forms of cooperation. The most important is the development of a welfare society, with the critical element being a guaranteed retirement income. A society which uses its economic growth to provide economic security not only treads lightly by removing the stress of chronic insecurity, but also entirely eliminates the principal private economic incentive to have children. Children change from being a large set of private "goods" into a smaller (but not too small) public good. In a welfare society, children represent the future of that society, and not just the separate futures of highly stressed families.

Some welfare states are better than others at achieving the lightness of tread and a deceleration of population growth. A welfare state that emphasises targeting creates divergent class communities, divergent values, and mutual suspicion between social classes. On the other hand, a society with a universally allocated social wage discourages social stratification, and enables a sufficient sharing of values to reach a measure of consensus on important matters such as conserving our planet.

A welfare state that emphasises individual work as the fundamental activity that defines self­reliance, and that sees society as an unbound collection of self­reliant individuals, focuses more on the increased payment of private wages through getting more people into work, and less on the social wage. It is a society that does not tread lightly, because it doesn't value cooperation, and doesn't acknowledge the value of the public domain or of the unpaid work that enhances it.

While certain forms of consumption weigh heavily on the planet, it is activities linked to market production that weigh heaviest. We consume more resources in work, and in getting to work, than we do in our homes. Work, promoted for its own sake as the most ethically virtuous of activities, negates the conservation ethic, the ethic that virtue should be equated not with activity but with treading lightly, with placing minimal stress on the earth's carrying capacity.

Along with Simon Collins, another journalist whom I have much respect for is the NZ Listener's Gordon Campbell. In a recent article ("Bad Sports", NZ Listener, 13 September), he wrote:

"More people are being sidelined in New Zealand, and turned into passive observers of the society they live in. In winner­take­all markets only a few succeed, though many are encouraged to strive. The result, in sport and in the economy - is a massive waste of human resources."

Campbell recognises that the values of the win­lose­lose struggle that is adversarial capitalism is very wasteful with respect to the losers' efforts; efforts which contribute to the depreciation of our planet and our infrastructure. Nevertheless, Campbell falls into the labourist trap of treating people as resources; resources, like land, that are there to be used, and, if not used, are wasted. The corollary of the man­as­resource world view is that waste is equated with inactivity, and that treading lightly on the planet might be sacrificed as a goal on the altar of the presently stronger ethic of "activity".

Ruth Richardson, as Minister of Finance, expressed the "productive activity at any cost" ethic in 1991 when she condemned "subsidised surfing" as a lifestyle. I take the opposite view. Surfers should be fed (see Philippe van Parijs, 1991, "Why Surfers Should be Fed; the Liberal Case for an Unconditional Basic Income" Philosophy and Public Affairs.), but not on hamburgers which create a heavy tread market for extensive cattle ranching. Surfers, as surfers, tread more lightly than corporate accountants. It is what they eat that matters, not whether they should be allowed to eat.

The people of Auckland in the 1890s were pushing their environment to its limits. Population growth turned out to be part of the solution, forcing better infrastructure, and not part of the problem. We still tread heavily on our environment, but not nearly as heavily, per person, as we did then. New Zealand can grow further without threatening its carrying capacity. On the other hand, if in the future we do destroy our habitat, the cause is much more likely to be conflict or ignorance than growth. The contrasting values that propel such conflict are those of exploitation (which generates private surpluses) versus economising (which facilitates social profit); and the labourist ethic that values work for its own sake and not for its net contribution to our sustenance, to our comfort, and to our happiness.

The effective marginal weight of tread can be less than zero if, as population rises, we increasingly value our habitat to the extent that the product of the earth's per capita carrying capacity and the earth's population actually falls.

© 1997 Keith Rankin

{ This document is:              http://www.oocities.org/Athens/Delphi/3142/krf31-popul_conf.html


 Back  to:  Rankin File  Archive
Keith Rankin's Page Go  to  Keith  Rankin's  page

( viewings since 28 Dec.'97: )