The Rankin File: #7



Adam Smith was an Economic Nationalist

Friday, 26 September 1997

In an earlier article, "Contrasting Views of the International Economy", I suggested that free trade could be argued for from three quite different points of view - nationalism, cosmopolitical economy, and ultra­imperialism - and that protectionism could be argued for from both national and cosmopolitan perspectives.

We have trouble understanding globalisation as a process of imperialism, in part because discourse in international economics has become confused by enduring myths that equate nationalism with protection and free trade with cosmopolitical economy.

Understanding the modern international economy - that of the real world rather than that of the undergraduate textbooks - can be enhanced through the appreciation of the nationalist origins of the free trade paradigm.

The founder of free trade theory - Adam Smith, the son of a Customs official who became a professor of Moral Philosophy at the University of Glasgow - was very much an economic nationalist. Smith's nationalism can be presented through the lens of the neoliberal Chicago political economist Douglas Irwin, the author of Against the Tide; an Intellectual History of Free Trade (1996, Princeton University Press).

Irwin says "Smith created such a compelling and complete case for free trade that commercial policy could no longer be seriously discussed without contending with his views.... Smith's case for free trade was based on its being in the national economic interest, not on some cosmopolitan ideal as he was later accused of by Friedrich List and others."

It was List and others, labelling themselves as economic nationalists, who did more than most to propagate the myth of Smith and his 'classical liberal' acolytes as cosmopolitan thinkers. List (The National System of Political Economy, 1841) regarded classical "cosmopolitical economy" - which claimed to maximise the economic wellbeing of all nations - as a covert way of legitimating a theory really intended to preserve Britain's dominance. Though his view was a valid characterisation of the free trade movements in 1840s' England, it was List, in promoting nationalism as a means of development for all nations towards an "economy of mankind" who was the more cosmopolitan of the two.

Smith set out his premises in his first major book, The Theory of Moral Sentiments (1759):

"The love of our own country seems not to be derived from the love of mankind.... France may contain, perhaps, near three times the number of inhabitants which Great Britain contains. In the great society of mankind, therefore, the prosperity of France should appear to be an object of much greater importance than that of Great Britain. The British subject, however, who upon that account, should prefer upon all occasions the prosperity of the former to that of the latter country, would not be thought a good citizen of Great Britain. We do not love our country merely as part of the great society of mankind: we love it for its own sake, and independently of any such consideration".

Smith saw the "Invisible Hand" (which he only mentioned once in his major work, The Wealth of Nations, 1776) as being a reflection of man's innate patriotism. People when not subject to government intervention on behalf of a "commercial system" strongly biased towards export­led growth - a "Restrictive and Prohibitory Commercial System" in the words of Jeremy Bentham in 1821 - would follow that form of patriotism otherwise known as enlightened self-interest:

"As every individual, therefore, endeavours as much as he can both to employ his capital in the support of domestic industry, and so to direct that industry that its produce may be of the greatest value; every individual necessarily labours to render the annual revenue of the society as great as he can. He generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it. By preferring the support of domestic to that of foreign industry, he intends only his own security; and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention."

Smith's "project of empire" [Wealth of Nations, Book 5] in fact favoured a strong domestic economy that incorporated Britain's colonies in Ireland and America; a commonwealth whose "natural" productive powers would bury Holland. For Smith, the Dutch commercial system of monopoly trade conducted through the East India and West India Companies represented everything that that wrong - that was "artificial" - about the international economy of his time.

Smith favoured free trade as a better means of dealing to the Dutch than the protection which prevailed in Britain during the industrial revolution that separated Smith in time from List. He spelt out his contempt for the "dour" Dutch, without mentioning them by name, in one memorable passage of The Wealth of Nations:

"The laudable motive of all these [British] regulations, is to extend our own manufactures, not by their own improvement, but by the depression of those of all our neighbours, and by putting an end, as much as possible, to the troublesome competition of such odious and disagreeable rivals".

Smith was actually a Francophile, incorporating much of French economics into his paradigm, as well as being a connoisseur of French wine. He was vehemently opposed to bilateral trading arrangements, such as that between England and Portugal, in part because he hated Portuguese wine!

Adam Smith favoured free international trade, despite his advocacy of domestic trade, as being preferable to the manipulated trade that epitomised the commercial system [Wealth of Nations, Book 4]:

"Every town and country, in proportion as they have opened their ports to all nations; instead of being ruined by this free trade, as the principles of the commercial system would lead us to expect, have been enriched by it."

Smith was no ultra­imperialist. But nor did he mean to create a cosmopolitan vision. His vision was of a world naturally dominated by a great Anglo-Celtic empire; a fraternal trans­Atlantic empire rather than an empire of tribute such as those of classical imperialism, of Dutch imperialism, or of 1990s' ultra­imperialism; a commonwealth founded on its natural resources, its domestic trade, and its superior "arts" (ie technology). Free trade arguments evolved, nevertheless, in the nineteenth and twentieth centuries, to serve the interests of the leaders of the industrialised commercial system; leading nations whose dominant interests have been essentially the same as those of the "odious" nations of Smith's time.

To follow through this story, a useful book is still Bernard Semmel's The Rise of Free Trade Imperialism (1970), which interestingly gives Edward Gibbon Wakefield a seminal role in the propagation of free trade empire. Indeed it was Wakefield's heavily annotated edition of Smith's Wealth of Nations, that was read by Victorian Britons.

© 1997 Keith Rankin


 Back  to:  Rankin File  Archive
Keith Rankin's Page Go  to  Keith  Rankin's  page

( viewings since 28 Dec.'97: )