go to Keith Rankin's site |
Keith's email contact is:
Published (abridged) in The Independent, (NZ),
pg.11, 16 Aug. 1996, under the title:
"List overrated in looking to past for today's economic truth".
The response to Chris Trotter's piece (26 July, 1996) on Friedrich List
- the early 19th century German political economist - suggests
that List might not be as little known or as little rated as has
been suggested. List is in fact one of those political economists,
like Adam Smith, whose place in history is distorted by bumper-sticker
misunderstandings about what he was really arguing.
Perhaps 99% percent of all texts on political economy from the
17th to the 19th century could be classed as nationalist, in that
they sought policy changes that would improve the economic performances
of the writers' nations. List was certainly no exception. Having
said that, List was in essence an economic liberal and a free
trader, both in public life and in his writings. While he was
no supporter of laissez-faire, he was by no means a spokesperson
for the collectivist left, nor a precursor of fascism. He believed
that governments had a positive role to play in improving the
efficacy of markets.
In the early 19th century, German governments were much less protectionist
than were British governments. Furthermore, Palmerstonian nationalism
in 1830s' to 1860s' Britain was no less vehement with the introduction
of free trade in the 1840s. Politicians such as Disraeli and economists
such as Cairnes continued to talk about 'tribute' as the purpose
of empire. As late as the 1900s, the world's most eminent economist
- Alfred Marshall - was asked to give policy recommendations about
how a commercial policy could be designed so as to get foreigners
to pay an increased share of British taxes. The political commitment
to British commercial interests on a world stage, while not a
"conspiracy", was real.
As Trotter noted, List's nationalism was accentuated during his
time in America. In Philadelphia in the 1820s, the main influences
on List were the late Alexander Hamilton, who as Federal Treasurer
in the 1790s became the focus of American support for manufacturing
development, and the more radical Daniel Raymond, whom some say
List plagiarised. Hamilton's two main influences were Adam Smith
and an anti-physiocratic banker from Geneva, Jacques Necker, who
had two stints as French finance minister in the 1770s and 1780s.
Necker was in power at the time of the storming of the Bastille,
but was not regarded as an enemy of the revolution and was never
threatened with the guillotine.
Indirectly - ie through Hamilton - Smith was a major influence
on List. It was a long serving Edinburgh economics professor -
J.S. Nicholson, an unreserved fan of Adam Smith - who noted as
much when in the 1900s he wrote a forward to a reprint of List's
National System of Political Economy. The main weakness
of List's book was seen by Nicholson as its anti-Smith rhetoric,
suggesting that many of List's statements about Smith reflected
popular interpretations rather than careful study. Indeed, most
people today who have strong views about Smith have not read his
Wealth of Nations, let alone his equally important Theory
of Moral Sentiments. It was the physiocratic elements of Smith,
portraying agriculture as the backbone of the national economy,
that List, like Hamilton before him, disagreed with.
Nicholson made other key points about List. List's most important
contribution to economic thought was his emphasis on the importance
of "intangible capital" to modern economic growth. Indeed,
it is only in the 1980s and 1990s that modern economics is coming
to appreciate the contribution of intangibles to GDP. At a political
level, List's text could give no support whatsoever for British
protectionist opinion. In the 1900s the Tory party was advocating
retaliatory protective tariffs as a means by which Britain might
retain its economic lead over Germany and the USA. It was only
because the political left strongly supported free trade that
Britain was able to fend off protectionism until the collapse
of the Labour Government in 1931.
List was what would be called today a 'development economist'.
He argued that both undeveloped and industrialised countries would
be best served by a free trade policy, regardless of the policies
of other countries. But he also argued that newly industrialising
countries, having commenced a process of development under free
trade, would need to go through a period of national 'producer
sovereignty' (to pick up on a term used by Owen McShane [August
2]) if they were to complete the transition to large scale industrialisation.
List accepted that the process would involve efficiency losses,
but believed that dynamic gains would offset those losses.
List, like Smith, Marx and many others, offered a 'stage theory'
of economic history. His theory advocated commercial policies
appropriate to each stage of development; List was a 'relativist'
in that he believed a nation's policies should reflect its circumstances.
History has largely proved List right, in that all bar none of
today's major industrial powers followed protectionist policies
during their critical 'take-off' stages. It is a moot point whether
List is relevant to New Zealand today, however, depending on one's
view of our present stage of development and our place as a very
small country in a big world.
List was regarded by the most eminent of the early neoclassical
economists as an important advocate of what would become American
institutionalism. Marshall respected List's views. Marshall's
successor as Cambridge economics professor, Pigou, stated in the
1900s: 'Of the formal validity of List's arguments there is no
longer any dispute among economists'.
List lived in an era of nascent national empires. Today's international
economy is different. All nations are seeing their sovereignty
challenged by international forces that are little understood.
National governments are increasingly prepared to pay homage to
international markets as a de facto sovereign. Under these
circumstances, it is perhaps another, more recent, German economist
who we should be looking to for guidance: Rudolf Hilferding who
published Finance Capital in 1910.
While there is nothing wrong with looking to specific economists
of the past for inspiration and understanding, we should also
seek new understandings of new situations. We should seek to address
today's burning issue, the determination of economic sovereignty,
in a disinterested way, through scholarship and informal public
debate. Unfortunately, it is very difficult for people to present
or even listen to arguments that undermine their immediate interests,
especially within an adversarial culture such as our own which
equates concession in argument with weakness.
Economics is controversial for one basic reason: economic debate
is not simply academic, participants and audiences have interests
to protect. For example, today's executives on very high salaries
do have an interest in stifling debate about why 1990s' markets
deliver them incomes vastly in excess of normal market remuneration.
Historically, private economic rents are evidence of protected
markets, of producer sovereignty, of insider coalitions. While
today's successful distributional coalitions differ from those
of List's day, it remains true that markets are more healthy when
economic surpluses are more evenly distributed.
© 1997 Keith Rankin
Keith Rankin teaches economic history at the University of Auckland.
![]() |
This is: http://www.oocities.org/Athens/Delphi/3142/krnkn_list_f.html