|
- Cost of Capital Estimation Models
-
- 1. Latent-Variable CAPM with Expected Risk Premium
(ERP)
- Wayne E. Ferson and Dennis H. Locke (1997)
-
- 2. Miller's Indifferent-Capital-Structure CAPM with
Tax Premium
- Gordon Sick (1997)
-
- 3. Multi-Beta CAPM with Size Premium
- Roger G. Ibbotson, Paul D. Kaplan, and James D. Peterson (1997)
-
- 4. Limited-Dependent-Variable CAPM with Transactions-Cost
Premium
- David A. Lesmond (1995)
-
- 5. Multi-Beta CAPM with Turnover Premium
- Shing-yang Hu (1997)
-
- 6. Multi-Beta CAPM with Distress Premium and
Dividend Yield
- S.P. Kothari and Jay Shaken (1997)
-
- 7. Multi-Beta CAPM with Country-Risk Premium
- Roger G. Ibbotson (1997)
-
- 8. CAPM with Bondholder-Stockholder-Conflict Premium
- Robert Parrino and Michael S. Weisbach (1997)
-
-
- Project/Division Cost of Capital Estimation Models
-
- 1. Pure-Play Beta and Idiosyncratic Variances
Minimization
- Marlena Akhbari, David Geltner, and Brian Kluger (1997)
-
- 2. Full-Information Industry Beta and Conglomerate Size
Effect
- Paul D. Kaplan and James D. Peterson (1997)
-
- 3. Accounting-Based Beta and Cluster Analysis
- Marcus A. Ingram (1997)
-
- Latent-Variable CAPM with Expected Risk Premium (ERP) Back to Top
-
- Practitioners needing estimates of a firm's cost of equity have long
relied on the CAPM. Recent evidence casts doubt on the validity of the CAPM and Beta.
However, there is not much evidence to gauge the importance of the rejections of the CAPM
in a practical decision-making context. This paper presents evidence on the sources of
error in the estimating cost of capital over time. We use a number of proxies for the true
MVE portfolio, allowing that the CAPM is the wrong model. The analyst is assumed to rely
on a standard market index. We find that the great majority of the error in estimating the
cost of capital is found in the risk premium estimate or the ERP, and relatively small
errors in the estimate of risk measure or the Beta. This suggests that analysts should
improve estimation procedures for market risk premiums, which are commonly based on
historical averages. This can be done by using regression models, such as appeared in the
finance literature, or by purchasing forecasts from firms which specialize in producing
them.
-
- To calculate a cost of equity, analysts often use historical average
returns as an estimate of the risk premium on a market index, combined with estimates of
beta according to the CAPM. Our simulations suggest that the accuracy of cost of capital
figures are likely to benefit from improving the estimates of the expected risk premium on
a standard market benchmark, even if the CAPM is the wrong model. Estimates that reflect
the current state of the economy may be purchased from specialists or generated in house
using straightforward regression analysis. When errors in the cost of capital over time
are the issue, improving the market risk premium estimate is much more important than are
concerns about using the wrong beta. Recent evidence that expected risk premiums vary with
the state of the economy raises a host of issues about the practice of capital budgeting,
and this article has merely scratched the surface. For example, our analysis followed the
common practice of using monthly data to develop the estimates, even though the results
may be used to evaluate cash flows many years into the future. However, studies find that
market indicators like the ones we use have higher explanatory power for long-horizon
returns than for short-horizon returns. Therefore, state dependence in required returns is
likely to be very important when formally incorporated into long-term capital budgeting
problems. Future research is needed to deepen understanding of the issues.
- Miller's Indifferent-Capital-Structure CAPM with Tax Premium Back to Top
-
- This paper examines the valuation implications of a Miller-style model
of capital structure. The popular weighted average cost of capital (WACC) and adjusted
present value (APV) formulas are generally cast in a model consistent with the MM model in
which there is value associated with interest tax shields. This paper addresses the
question of how to calculate value as those interest tax shields converge to zero because
of differential taxation of debt and equity income at the personal level. The paper shows
that the zero-beta rate of return in the CAPM for equity assets should be an after-tax
debt rate, not a risk-free rate. This suggests that the equity risk premium for a unit of
beta risk is larger than thought before and this paper explores the impact of this on the
cost of equity. With this modification to the cost of equity, the WACC formula still
holds. Modifications to the APV formula are shown that properly recognize leverage and tax
issues. It is derived on a certainty-equivalent basis and discounts interest tax shields
at a cost of riskless equity (zero-beta CAPM) rather than riskless debt.
-
- This paper has explored the valuation implications of the Miller (1977)
equilibrium for capital structure indifference with personal and corporate taxation. It
has extended the model to allow cross-sectional variation in corporate tax rates and
explored the necessary revisions to the CAPM and to the APV formula. The model requires a
distinction between the return on riskless debt and on zero-beta equity. The zero-beta
equity return is an after-tax return on riskless debt where the tax rate is the tax rate
of a marginal firm that is indifferent to the taxation of debt and equity income in a
Miller debt and taxes world. This marginal firm's tax rate is not directly observable, but
a lower bound for the zero-beta equity return is provided by the return on riskless
tax-exempt municipal bonds and an upper bound is provided by the expected return on the
global minimum variance portfolio of equity assets. Given the model, the market price of
risk is larger than typically measured by the average excess return on an equity market
portfolio relative to riskless bonds. This means that the capital market line in the CAPM
is steeper than originally thought. This theory suggests that there is merit in
empirically estimating the zero-beta return on riskless equity and reassessing historical
market risk premia. Given the revised measure of the cost of equity, the model is
consistent with traditional WACC. However, APV formulas should be modified to recognize
that the certainty equivalent of the rate of return on riskless debt is the return on
riskless debt and that resulting interest tax shield should be discounted at the cost of
riskless equity rather than at a cost of debt.
- Multi-Beta CAPM with Size Premium Back to Top
-
- The authors adjust estimates of systematic risk (the betas) for
cross-autocorrelations in security returns. They show that substantial positive
adjustments to beta are necessary for small firms. Traditional estimates of beta are
unrelated to future returns over the 1931 through 1994 time period, whereas adjusted
estimates are positively correlated with future returns. In addition, adjusted beta
estimates partially account for the size effect in common stock returns.
-
- No commercial beta services provide estimates of systematic risk that
account for the lagged price response of small firms to market wide information. Our
results indicate that beta estimates for small firms are severely biased downwards.
Traditional beta estimates are unrelated to future returns. However, adjusted estimates of
beta display the positive risk-return tradeoff implied by the CAPM. In addition, adjusted
beta estimates are capable of accounting for part of the size effect in stock returns.
Based on these results, we recommend commercial beta services incorporate the information
contained in prior market returns.
- Limited-Dependent-Variable CAPM with Transactions-Cost Premium Back to Top
-
- Downward biased systematic risk estimates are caused by
transaction-costs- induced zero returns which alter the relation between daily security
returns and the market index. These zero returns dominate the return structure for both
small and large firms. On average, small firms exhibit over 40% zero returns while the
largest size firm deciles experience over 12% zero returns. The CAPM based market model,
which does not specifically reflect the preponderance of zero returns, produces beta
estimates that are negatively related to average portfolio returns. Unfortunately, firm
size better explains portfolio returns than does beta. However, specifically incorporating
these zero returns in the return generating process produces beta estimates that are
positively and significantly related to average portfolio returns. Firm size is largely
reduced to insignificance.
-
- Zero returns dominate the trading patterns of small firms and are even
significantly present in the trading behavior of large firms. The number of zero returns
experienced by small firms are as high as 85% of the daily return observations for a given
year. Larger firms experience as many as 40% zero returns for a given year. The large
number of zero returns is caused by transaction costs. A regression test of this premise
reveals a strong association, 35% R2 for the aggregate regression tests, between
transaction costs and the induced number of zero returns. These zero returns reveal the
effects that transaction costs exert on daily security returns. The influence of these
zero returns necessitates a regression technique that incorporates the effects of
transaction costs in systematic risk estimation.
-
- The technique used to better estimate market risk is the Limited
Dependent Variable (LDV) regression model. This model uses the preponderance of zero
returns as an endogenously specified return variable that proxies for the influence of
transaction costs. These transaction costs are modeled by the LDV model's intercept terms
and are shown to be vary in inversely with firm size. The OLS market model does not
specifically reflect the influence of the transaction-costs induced zero returns. The
market model specification for the return generating process assumes that security returns
continuously reflect the market return index because systematic risk is the only priced
element. The zero returns signal that this assumption is not valid. Failure to
specifically reflect the transaction-costs induced zero returns results in an omitted
variable problem because systematic risk is not universally applicable across all market
returns. In essence, the risk-return relation is no longer linear. The non-linearity
causes a downward bias in the OLS market model's systematic risk estimator because of
omitted variables. The omitted variables are transaction costs, LDV systematic risk, and
the asset's own variance. The more zero returns a security experiences, the more downward
biased the OLS systematic risk estimates become.
-
- The OLS systematic risk estimates demonstrate the trend that smaller
firms have lower systematic risk estimates than do large firms. Evidently, when using the
OLS systematic risk estimates, small firms are less risky than large firms yet earn higher
returns. Comparisons between the OLS and the LDV model demonstrate the downward bias in
the OLS systematic risk estimates. The LDV model's systematic risk estimates, on the other
hand, more properly show that small firms are three times as risky as large firms and that
the returns associated with small firms are commensurate with risk. Fama-MacBeth's tests
of the relation between monthly portfolio returns and OLS systematic risk estimates along
with firm size show that as average returns increase, the OLS systematic estimates
decrease. This result is opposite to the economic intuition of the CAPM and illustrates
the degree of the downward bias in OLS systematic risk estimates due to the zero returns.
Market capitalization is invariably negative and significant, thus reinforcing the firm
size effect when using an OLS methodology. On the other hand, the LDV risk estimates
demonstrate a positive and significant relation with average portfolio returns. In
addition, the market capitalization variable (size premium) is insignificant in almost
every sub-period tested. The LDV model provides a more economically rational relation
between average portfolio returns and market risk as well as reducing the explanatory
power of firm size. Indeed, the effects of firm size are all but removed from explaining
average portfolio returns once the zero returns are reflected in the market risk
estimation process. The viability of beta in explaining portfolio returns is still
apparent.
- Multi-Beta CAPM with Turnover Premium Back to Top
-
- This paper tries to find a widely accessible measure of liquidity and
studies its impact on asset pricing. Using trading turnover as a measure of liquidity and
the 1976-1993 Tokyo Stock Exchange data, cross-sectionally, stocks with higher turnover
have lower expected returns. This evidence is consistent with predictions derived from an
Amihud-Mendelson type of transaction cost model in which the turnover measures marginal
investors' trading frequency. The trading frequency hypothesis also predicts that the
cross-sectional expected return is a concave function of the turnover and time-series
expected return is an increasing function of the turnover. The Japanese data supports both
predictions.
-
- Turnover can forecast expected stock returns and the observed relation
is consistent with the hypothesis that the turnover measures marginal investors' trading
frequency. The evidence provided here, however, can only suggest that the trading
frequency effect exists and is stronger than the information-based trading and the
order-processing cost effects. To further disentangle these effects, future research need
to measure the transaction costs and examine the relation between expected returns,
turnover, and transaction costs at the same time.
- Multi-Beta CAPM with Distress Premium and Dividend Yield
Back to Top
-
- We find reliable evidence that both book-to-market and dividend yield
track time-series variation in expected real stock returns over the period 1926-91 (in
which B/M is stronger) and the subperiod 1941-91 (in which dividend yield is stronger). A
Bayesian bootstrap procedure implies that an investor with prior belief 0.5 that expected
returns on the equal-weighted index are never negative comes away from the full-period B/M
evidence with posterior probability 0.08 for the hypothesis (0.14 with the impact of the
1933 outlier tempered). Although this raises doubts about market efficiency, the post-1940
evidence is consistent with expected returns always being positive.
-
- The B/M results suggest that expected return variation over the 1926-91
period was not driven entirely by equilibrium changes in compensation for risk. Rather, it
appears that the market may have been inefficient, particularly in the late 1920s and
early 1930s, a period of great economic volatility. The stronger results for the
equal-weighted index, which is influenced more by small-firm returns, is consistent with
this conclusion, although greater variation in risk-related predictability is also
plausible for smaller firms.
-
- The market inefficiency conclusion should be tempered by several
observations. First, there is the familiar element of data mining which implies that the
significance of extreme results is overstated, although by how much it is difficult to
say. While the financial ratios considered here can be motivated theoretically, dividend
yield is examined in part because of its prominence as compared to earnings yield in past
time-series study. B/M is considered primarily because of its recently acquired celebrity
status in explaining cross-sectional stock return variation, although the extent to which
this biases time-series results at the market level is less clear. These concerns and the
fact that the forecasting power of B/M and dividend yield varies considerably over
different subperiods give further credence to the idea that data mining consideration
should temper one's assessment of the value of these ratios in making future investment
decisions.
-
- The dividend yield slope estimate for the 1926-91 period and all of the
estimates for the 1941-91 subperiod are more reasonable than the B/M results, but still
substantial, implying expected return movements from three to eight percentage points for
one-standard-deviation changes in the financial ratios. These estimates all result in
varying degrees of increased confidence in the proposition that expected returns were
never negative. While the considerable estimated variation in expected returns might be
difficult to reconcile with market efficiency, the hypothesis that the slope is greater
than three is never rejected at the 0.05 level. Definitive statements concerning the
extent to which estimated variation in expected returns is related to risk or systematic
mispricing (or both) require further analysis.
- Multi-Beta CAPM with Country-Risk Premium Back to Top
-
- The law of one price implies that any differences in the rates of
inflation will be offset by a change in the exchange rate. It suggests that in order to
estimate changes in the spot rate of exchange, we need to estimate differences in
inflation rates. It also implies that inflation-adjusted exchange rate (or real exchange
rate) should have been constant. The law of one interest rate (or capital market
equilibrium) assumes that there is a single real rate of interest in the world capital
markets if they are fully integrated. Since government cannot directly control interest
rates in the international markets, we might expect that in these markets differences
between the expected real rates of interest would be small. But the government has more
control in domestic short-term interest rates. It is possible for a country to have a real
interest rate that is below the real rate in other countries. Individuals and companies
are capable of transferring their capital from countries with low real interest rates to
those with high real rates. The international CAPM assumes that all securities are priced
in perfectly integrated markets and investors measure returns in different currencies. The
riskfree rate can be in any currency if international fisher parity holds. The risk
premium and the beta can be measured relative to the integrated market. In the segmented
markets, the costs of capital vary for different countries but are in equilibrium assuming
fair pricing. However, in the emerging markets where inflation rates are high and asset
prices are unstable and volatile, the cost of capital must take into account the country
risk in addition to the market risk premium. In this event, controlling cost of capital is
more important than measuring it. The designated currency for receipts of cash flow has
large effect.
-
- In summary, cost of capital is an equilibrium rate assuming fair
pricing. International parity relates interest rate differences to differences in expected
inflation rates, forward currency rates, and expected currency movements. The
international CAPM can be based on any currency and estimates of risk premium and beta
that are mutually consistent. Emerging markets costs of capital are very high primarily
because of country risk (political and domestic economic risks). some of which can be
mitigated.
- CAPM with Bondholder-Stockholder-Conflict Premium Back to Top
-
- This paper examines the importance of stockholder-bondholder conflicts
in capital structure choice. We compute the expected magnitude of the wealth transfer
between stockholders and bondholders when a firm accepts a new equity-financed project and
then characterize the set of positive NPV projects that stockholders would prefer to
ignore (the underinvestment problem) and the set of negative NPV projects that
stockholders would like to accept (the overinvestment problem). The results quantify the
distortions from both underinvestment and overinvestment and verify that both increase
with the quantity of debt in the capital structure. However, these distortions appear too
small to offset the value of the tax shields associated with debt, and thus are unable to
explain the vast majority of cross-sectional variation in capital structures.
-
- Despite over 40 years of research on the topic, we still know little
about the determinants of capital structure. There is general agreement that debt has a
tax advantage over equity, but we know little about the relative importance of the costs
of debt that potentially offset this tax advantage. Among the most popular explanations
for the relatively low debt levels that we observe are those proposed by Myers (1977) and
Jensen and Meckling (1976) that agency problems inherent in the differing objectives of
stockholders and bondholders offset the tax advantage of debt. It has been argued that
stockholder-bondholder conflicts are an important determinant of capital structure (Smith
and Watts, 1992), have major consequences for the way firms reorganize when in financial
distress (Gertner and Scharfstein, 1991), and even have macroeconomic implication (Lamont,
1995).
-
- We document that the distortion exists and that it increases with debt
levels. The stockholder of the median firm on Compustat would choose to accept a low risk
project only if the return is at least 8,12%, assuming that the project pays annual cash
flows equal to 10% of expected annual cash flows and the projects has a zero NPV with a
discount rate of 7.96%. This hurdle rate rises with the amount of debt in the capital
structure. If we increase the debt ratio to 40%, the hurdle rate increases to 8.35%. This
calculation quantifies the underinvestment effect first proposed by Myers (1977). As the
project's risk increases, the relevant hurdle rate drops closer to the all-equity
benchmark rate. Eventually, the project enters the overinvestment range, in which the
hurdle rate for new projects is lower than that required for the project to have a zero
NPV. In this range, stockholders have incentive to overinvest in risky negative NPV
projects.
-
- The rate at which the hurdle rate drops depends on the correlation
between the firm's and project's cash flows. If the correlation is low, the project
provide diversification, reducing the overall risk and transferring wealth to bondholders.
If the correlation is high, then this diversification effect is reduced and a lower risk
level is required to get overinvestment. Our model tells us which types of projects the
firm should accept and ignore when investment decisions are made in the interest of
stockholders. Its limitation is that it is impossible to know which projects firms are
actually passing up, since firms' investment opportunity sets are inherently unobservable
(i.e. strategic real options). However, our analysis does tell us the rates of return for
any projects that the firm does pass up because of these conflicts. We construct a test of
whether Myers's arguments can explain the capital structure decisions of typical firms.
Given the rates of return implicit in the projects that are passed up, we estimate how
much investment the firm would have to make to justify ignoring the tax shields. Our
results imply that the firm would have to invest approximately 38.5 times annual after-tax
cash flow, or 4.5 times total firm value, in order to create enough value to justify
giving up the tax shields that the firm could realize if it increased its debt ratio to
40%. This calculation suggests that the underinvestment problem, while one of a number of
costs of debt, is unable to explain capital structure choices for typical firms.
-
- Given the amount of debt used by a firm, the increase in
stockholder-bondholder conflicts associated with additional debt are too small to explain
why the firm does not use more debt. Thus, conflicts alone cannot explain the
well-documented cross-sectional patterns between firms' asset and capital structures. One
characteristic of the equilibria in a number of recent theoretical papers is that the
maturities of a firm's assets and liabilities are matched. Since the growth options of
many equity-financed firms have extremely long horizons while the assets-in-place
associated with debt-financed firms typically have shorter durations, this characteristic
is consistent with the empirical evidence. Nonetheless, it seems clear that progress in
explaining capital structure will require distinguishing between the theoretical arguments
in the literature. Numerical analysis in this study is one way in which this can be
accomplished. We should emphasize that there are a number of limitations on this analysis
that should be addressed in future work. We have argued that our basic conclusions are
likely to be robust to the choice of discount factors and to the fact that we ignore
intertemporal project interactions. In addition, we assume throughout the paper that cash
flows follow a random walk. A more sophisticated model of cash flows would yield more
accurate measures of investment distortions. Finally, we assume that strict priority
always holds and that there are no direct or indirect bankruptcy costs. Clearly, it would
be an improvement to replace these assumptions with more realistic ones.
- Pure-Play Beta and Cost of Capital Back to Top
-
- The pure-play method for estimating the cost of capital for a project
requires the analyst to identify one or more publicly traded firms that operate in a
similar line of business. These firms must be pure-play, i.e., they must not have
significant operations in other lines of business. If pure-play firms can be identified,
market information on these firms can be used to estimate the cost of capital for the
project. A major difficulty is that many firms operate in multiple lines of business.
-
- Prior researchers have addressed this difficulty using mathematical
programming (Boquist and Moore, 1983) or regression (Erhardt and Bhagwat, 1991) to
estimate industry (sector) betas using estimates of security (company) betas along with
the industry compositions of the securities. Specifying betas for each industry implies a
specific company beta for a company with given proportions in each industry. The
mathematical program or regression selects the sector betas to minimize the deviations
between the implied company betas and observed company betas.
-
- This paper takes a different approach by framing the problem as an
investment question. We demonstrate how to construct a portfolio which approximates a
pure-play in a target sector, using a combination of publicly traded stocks each of which
is not purely involved in the target sector. The idea is to build a portfolio to replicate
the investment returns to a specified target sector without any direct exposure to other
sectors. This is accomplished using long positions in some publicly traded stocks and
short positions in others in order to eliminate exposure in unwanted sectors. Geltner and
Kluger (1997) illustrates how to construct such a portfolio and consider its properties
and suitability for real estate investment (both speculative and hedging) as well as for
constructing real estate indices. This paper illustrates how the methodology can also be
used for estimating a project's cost of capital.
-
- The pure-play portfolio obtains maximum diversification in the pure-play
sector, and simultaneously eliminates exposure in non-target sectors by using short
positions. This methodology has several potential applications. It can be used as an
investment vehicle to either speculate or hedge in a specific industry, or geographic
sector of the economy. Similarly, sectoral or geographic return indices are a by-product
of the returns to the pure play.
-
- The pure-play technique, as described in many Corporate Finance
textbooks (e.g., Rao) is a well accepted method for approximating a project's cost of
capital. The primary difficulty in applying the technique occurs if there are no or few
publicly traded firms in the industry of interest. In such cases, the methodology
presented here can be used to build a pure-play portfolio using firms that operate in
multiple lines of business.
-
- Building a pure-play portfolio requires two main inputs: the percentage
of each firms' value broken down by industry (sector), and the relative idiosyncratic
variance terms. There can be up to nxt distinct idiosyncratic variance terms, one for each
industry (j=1,...,t) for every firm (i=1,...,n), x being the fraction of ith firm invested
in jth industry. For our illustration, we used very simple assumptions about these inputs.
We used the firm's revenue shares in each industry as a proxy for the corresponding
percent of market value. In addition, we assumed that the idiosyncratic variance term were
all equal (homoskedasticity). Clearly more complex and realistic alternative assumptions
are possible. Further research needs to be carried out to enumerate and evaluate such
assumptions, and to determine when and if the idiosyncratic variances might be estimated
using past market data.
- Full-Information Industry Beta Back to Top
-
- Since estimates of beta for individual firms contain a great deal of
statistical noise, analysts often estimate beta by averaging the betas of firms who
specialized in a similar line of business. Conglomerates are typically excluded from the
set of potential pure play since their operations span more than one line of business. Yet
conglomerates can be large firms that account for a significant market share in a
particular line of business. Large firms tend to have lower betas than small firms.
Therefore, pure-play beta estimates will likely be upwardly biased. In this study, betas
are estimated for 66 industries using the pure-play approach and a full-information
approach. The full-information approach incorporates industry-specific information
contained in the betas of conglomerates into the beta estimation process. Full-information
betas and their corresponding standard errors are substantially smaller than their
pure-play counterparts.
-
- Industry cost of capital calculations are complicated by the fact that
many firms operate in multiple industries. The observable betas for those firms who
operate in more than one line of business are weighted averages of the unobservable betas
of the individual operations. Therefore, these conglomerates are typically excluded from a
pure-play industry analysis. However, conglomerates can often large players in a
particular industry. The analysis of this study reveals that traditional calculations
pure-play industry betas are biased up. This follows from the fact that conglomerates tend
to be large firms and large firms tend to have low betas. Conglomerates can be
incorporated into the industry beta estimate via regression equation. An important
advantage associated with the cross-sectional regression methodology is that the resultant
full-information industry betas are more precise.
- Accounting-Based Beta Back to Top
-
- This study proposes and tests a practical method for selecting publicly
traded firms which can serve as proxies for private firms, division, or projects in
divisional cost of capital estimation problems. The cluster analysis method introduced
herein is an approach to divisional cost of capital estimation which utilizes accounting
variables to select a portfolio of publicly traded proxy firms. This method builds on the
intuition of Fuller and Kerr's (1981) pure-play proxy technique and utilizes cluster
analysis, which Elton and Gruber (1970) and others have shown to be useful in grouping
firms by their systematic risk. Empirical tests of this method are performed on a random
sample of 30 firms. These tests utilize CAPM estimated expected returns as the benchmark
by which to compare firms' suitability to serve as divisional cost of capital proxies.
These tests show that the estimates given by the cluster analysis method approach the CAPM
benchmarks, and the hypothesis that they are equivalent to these benchmarks cannot be
rejected. As a result, we conclude that cluster analysis is useful for identifying
divisional cost of capital proxies.
-
- The divisional cost of capital problem continues to be important for
practitioners and researchers alike. It is frequently desirable to be able to estimate the
market-priced risk of assets (e.g., divisions or projects) which do not have
publicly-traded dividend-paying equity securities. CAPM is a widely accepted method of
estimating the market-priced risk for firms with publicly-traded securities, so CAPM
estimates of expected returns were taken as benchmarks. Cluster analysis was used to
select proxies for target firms (pseudo-divisions) based on their accounting data. The
cluster analysis method was shown to be useful in predicting the CAPM expected return of a
target using that target's accounting data by selecting proxies for the target from
publicly traded firms. Further, it was established that some of the measured discrepancies
between targets' returns and proxies' returns are likely attributable to shortcomings in
using the CAPM on ex post data for benchmark returns rather than to deficiencies in the
cluster analysis approach. These results establish the usefulness of the cluster analysis
approach to divisional cost of capital estimation and the potential benefits of further
research in this area.
-
Back to Top
* Worapot Ongkrutaraksa is a lecturer in
Finance and Strategic Management at Maejo University's Faculty of Agricultural Business,
Chiang Mai, Thailand. He used to conduct his post-graduate research in financial economics
at Kent State University and international political economy at Harvard University through
the Fulbright sponsorship between 1995 and 1998.
E-mail: worapot@starmail.com
Home Page
|