|
- Introduction
The surge of financial derivatives usages in today's capital markets
and their applications in corporate finance has been the result of increasing uncertainty
and volatility in the underlying asset prices and returns which necessitate risk
management and control strategies. Forward contracts have long been used as hedging
vehicle by corporate financiers to achieve their desirable levels of business and
financial risk reduction. Nevertheless, some market participants find forward contracts
inflexible and risky in terms of their low liquidity and non-performance settlements. By
1972, the Chicago Mercantile Exchange (MERC) first introduced the standardized futures
contracts on foreign exchanges (e.g., Eurodollars) in their International Monetary Market
(IMM). The institutionalization of futures exchange permits both the individuals and
corporations to trade futures contracts derived from other kinds of underlying assets such
as government securities (Treasury bills, notes, and bonds) and stock indices like the
Standard & Poor's (S&P) 500.
-
- Financial forward and futures contracts represent a commitment by one
party to make delivery of the underlying asset to the contract's counterparty for a cash
payment in the future date. Besides being the hedging instruments, forward and futures are
used by market speculators and arbitrageurs to enhance their returns margin. Although no
initial cash transfer between parties is required for both forward and futures contracts,
certain distinctive features between them should be noted. The terms and conditions in the
forward contract are set by the parties to the contract through negotiation. The delivery
date and forward price are predetermined at the time the contract is entered into. The
futures contract's terms and conditions, on the other hand, are more standardized than
those specified in the forward contract with four special features. First, the exchange
(e.g., the MERC) who acts as counterparty to futures contracts prespecifies the maturity
date, delivery location, quality and quantity of the security to be delivered per
contract. Second, the exchange guarantees the performance of both clearing firms involved
in the futures trade. Third, positions in futures contracts can be liquidated prior to the
maturity date of the contract by taking an offsetting position in the identical contracts.
And fourth, the gain or loss on a futures position is marked to market, settled, and
cleared through daily cash payments. These four special characteristics provide added
protection against illiquidity, default (or credit risk), and settlement risks for futures
contracts over forward contracts.
-
- Theoretical Basis for Futures Pricing Back to Top
-
- The simple futures pricing model is based on the principle of
arbitrage-free, forward-expected spot prices relationship. Other more empirically relevant
models include the capital asset pricing model (CAPM), the net hedging pressure (NHP)
theory, and the cost of carry model (CCM). Theoretically, the forward price at which
arbitrage opportunity cannot occur is:
-
- FWt = St(1+i)T = E[St+T]
- where
- FWt = market value of forward contract at time t
- St = spot or cash price of the underlying security at time 0
- i = rate of return of the risk-free security, i.e., interest rate
- T = time to maturity of forward contract
- E[St+T] =
expected future spot price of the underlying security at time t+T
-
- Haugen (1986) suggests that since futures contracts are traded on the
exchange, there exist some discrepencies and relationship between forward and futures
contract prices. The difference in the cash flows results in a divergence between the two
prices:
-
- Ft = FWt + RP - DP
-
- where
- Ft = futures contract price at time t
- RP = reinvestment premium
- DP = delivery premium
-
- Reinvestment premium depends on the relationship of the covariance
between the spot price of the underlying security and the level of risk-free interest
rate. If the relationship is positive, then RP will be positive, and vice versa. If the
underlying security is T-bond, then RP will be negative since T-bond price and interest
rate are inversely correlated. The delivery premium is negative because the futures
provides the contract seller the options with respect to the exact nature of the
underlying security that can be delivered to the buyer. The contract buyer, therefore,
demands a discount on futures price, i.e., the negative DP, which depends on the
degree of latitude the seller has in terms of delivery and the extent to which the futures
price can be adjusted on delivery to fit the character of the underlying security.
-
- Based on the CAPM, a change in the futures price is proportional to the
changes in the term premium of the risk-free rate and the market risk premium. If this
relationship holds, futures price is considered an unbiased estimator of the expected
future spot price. However, it is found through empirical studies by Dusak (1973) and
Bodie and Rosanksy (1980) that the betas of commodity futures contracts approach zero.
Hence, this implies that the market risk premium on commodity futures is also zero.
Nontheless, Bodie and Rosanksy observe that commodity futures have positive returns. This
contradiction occurs because the stock market beta is not an appropriate measure of risk
for commodity futures since it cannot capture idiosyncratic risk of each kind of
commodities. They, therefore, conclude that stock-maket-based CAPM cannot be used to value
commodity futures contract accurately.
-
- The NHP theory postulates that futures returns are biased against the
net hedging position in favor of the net speculative position. Following Keynes (1930),
Hicks (1946), and Houthakker (1957), if the futures are underpriced, creating excess
returns for long speculators, then there exists a situation known as normal
backwardation. In this situation, net short hedging exceeds net long speculation. If,
on the other hand, the futures are overpriced, the opposite situation occurs. This
situation is called a contango where net long hedging exceeds net short
speculation. Both of these two NHP situations are rejected by many empirical studies by
Rockwell (1967), Fama and French (1987), Hartzmark (1987), Murphy and Hilliard (1989),
Phillips and Weiner (1991), and Kolb (1992) which shall be discussed later. Therefore, NHP
theory is not empirically powerful enough to serve as accurate pricing basis for futures
contracts.
-
- One other model remains which is the cost of carry model. The CCM is
used to measure the relationship between the spot price of the underlying security and its
futures price. It assumes that the short-positioned futures arbitrageurs borrow funds to
purchase the underlying security in the spot market and deliver it when the futures
contract matures. The CCM is similar to the forward pricing model as follow:
-
- FVt = St(1+i)T = Ft = E[St+T]
-
- where
- FVt = theoretical value of futures contract at time t
- Ft = market price of futures contract at time t
- St = spot price of the underlying security at time t
- i = rate of return on risk-free security, i.e., interest rate
- T = time to maturity of futures contract
-
- The theoretical value and the market price of the futures contract are
assumed to be equal under the perfect capital markets' conditions which include perfect
competition, frictionless markets, complete information, homogeneous beliefs, and
individual rationality. When the conditions of perfect markets are relaxed, arbitrage
opportunities exist. If FVt = St(1+i)T < Ft,
an arbitrage position can be set by selling (short) the relatively overpriced Ft and
buying (long) the fairly priced security in the spot market with St amount of
lending (short) at i to be paid back in T periods. The net cash position is zero, since
the arbitrageur is long in security while being short in the loan with identical amount.
The riskless profit is locked in at time t and to be paid off at the marutiry date
t+T. If FVt = St(1+i)T > Ft, then the opposite positions are required in futures (long), spot
(short), and borrowing (long) transactions to lock in the profit at time t. Yet, these
arbitrage opportunities exist in a very short-time horizon due to certain impediments to
riskless profit including transaction costs, short-selling restrictions, borrowing/lending
limitations and rates divergence, and the volatility of the risk-free interest rate.
-
- There are certain relationships among FV, F, and i which are worth
discussing. Cox, Ingersoll, and Ross (1981) infer the relationship between FV and F from
the correlations between F and i. If i and F are positively correlated, then F should be
greater than FV. In case of FV = F and when i and F rise together, the long futures
position gains and the short loses. The short futures pays long futures in cash at day's
end. The long, in turn, lends this cash amount at relatively high interest rate. When i
and F fall together, the long position loses while the short gains. The long pays cash to
the short and borrows the amount she pays at a relatively low interest rate. The reverse
of these positions is true if the correlation between i and F is negative. That is, F
should be less than FV when i moves in the oppositie direction to F. At market equilibrium
when FV = F and when i rises (falls) and F falls (rises), the short futures position gains
(loses) and the long loses (gains) at day's end. The short futures position receives
(pays) cash from (to) the long and lends (borrows) it at a relatively high (low) interest
rate.
-
- Some Futures Trading Strategies Back to Top
-
- Stock Index Futures Arbitrage
-
- The futures contracts on stock indices offer some arbitrage
opportunities to those traders who could discover price discrepency between FV and F. The
main source of price differential can be attributed to the presence of dividends received
from holding stocks in the index and the financing costs incurred in either lending or
borrowing transactions. Thus, the theoretical value of stock index futures is given by:
-
- FVt = St(1+i)T - D = Ft
-
- where
- D = dividends received from holding stocks in the index up to t+T
-
- In setting up the arbitrage positions for stock index futures, the net
financing costs (NFC), i.e., the difference between dividend yield and interest rate,
must be taken into account. The stock index futures is overpriced when F - S > NFC, and underpriced when F - S < NFC. The arbitrage positions can be
set accordingly following the logic discussed earlier in the previous section. For
example, the short futures arbitrage takes place when F is overpriced. This is
accomplished by selling (short) stock index futures, buying (long) stock index spot,
lending (short) the cash amount equal to stock index price, and receiving cash dividends.
Since the profit from short position in futures and long position in spot exceeds the NFC,
riskless arbitrage results. In contrast, the long future arbitrage occurs when F is
underpriced. The positions are set up as follow: buying (long) stock index in the futures
market, selling (short) stock index in the spot market, borrowing (long) the amount
equivalent to the index price, and forgoing the cash dividends. As a result, the NFC must
be greater than the profit made from the difference between the futures and spot index
prices.
-
- The difficulty in determining the NFC poses certain risk in setting up
the stock index arbitrage positions. This risk is caused by the timing and the stream of
dividends which cannot be determined as easily as the more certain interest rate. Another
difficulty stems from the fact that stock index futures price sometimes leads the spot
price of the index itself. This further complicates the identification of the futures
contract's mispricing. Moreover, the perfectly hedged positions between stock index spot
and leveraging may not be achievable due to dividends' uncertainty and increased
transaction costs.
-
- Dynamic Portfolio Insurance
-
- Dynamic portfolio insurance can be viewed as an alternative strategy to
stock index futures arbitrage that is used to protect the capital gains of the current
portfolio without conceding the opportunity for future capital gains when the prices or
the indices rise. It effectively guarantees the minimum selling price of the portfolio or
stock index should the markets decline while allowing unlimited gains on the up-side
should the markets rally. The price risk in the spot markets can be hedged by taking a
short portfolio futures position while going long in spot portfolio position. The short
futures position serves as an insurance against the down-side price risk without making
any initial cash outlay. Portfolio insurance can be obtained through taking the long
positions both in the underlying security and the put option. However, this option-based
strategy incurs initial cash payment in the form of put premium whenever the put contract
is entered into. It is noteworthy that during the stock market crash of 1987, dynamic
portfolio insurance activities and program trading (i.e., simulataneously buying and
selling large number of stocks to adjust or reblance the current portfolios in a single
execution to exploit timing advantage and save transaction costs) were blamed as being its
primary causes since there had been more short portfolio positions than long in both
futures and spot markets which put more pressure to sell and result in prices to cascade
downward even furtuer very rapidly. The phenomenon experienced then can be perceived as
being either the market prices adjustment toward their fundamental values or the
overreaction in both the underlying securities and the derivatives markets. It leads
researchers and market regulators to ponder the empirical evidence with respect to the
issues of derivatives mispricing and the need for price adjustment mechanisms (e.g.,
circuit breaker) and the issue of lead-lag effects between the spot and futures markets.
- Empirical Evidence of Futures Trading
-
- Futures Mispricing Effects Back to Top
-
- The studies conducted in this area have focused on the cross-sectional
price discrepencies between the theoretical value of futures derived from the spot price
of the underlying security and the market value of such futures contract. Dusak (1973) and
Bodie and Rosansky (1980) base their studies on the CAPM to determine the betas of
commoditiy futures market in relation to the stock market. They find that commodity
futures betas approach zero with positive intercept. Breeden (1979, 1980) uses his
consumption-based CAPM to test the futures-spot price relationships of a basket of
commodity goods. He finds that the betas are positive for livestock but negative for
grains, which imply the absence of common measure of commodity-market risk premium from
which mispricing can be determined. Fama and French (1987) test the normal backwardation
hypothesis under the NHP theory and find more evidence against it. Murphy and Hilliard
(1989) observes the disappearance of underpriced commodity futures after the first oil
shock of 1973. Hartzmark (1987) studies the aggregate profits of futures speculators and
arbitrageurs and finds weak evidence to support the existence of normal backwardation or
contango. Phillips and Weiner (1991) conducts similar test to Hartzmark using intraday
trades in the petroleum forward markets and concludes that no group of oil traders, except
the Japanese trading firms, can make substantial profits on the daily basis. Kolb (1992)
shows that only 7 out of 29 futures contracts have the evidence of mispricings (both
contango and normal backwardation), based on one million daily futures prices. He
concludes that currency and bond futures have provided unbiased estimates of their
expected spot prices.
-
- Lead and Lag Effects
-
- The lead-lag effects of futures prices on spot prices are concerned with
the timing differences between the two which result in the price discovery when futures
lead spot and the mispricing when they lag. Since futures contracts trading are less
expensive than spot transactions, futures markets seem to be more efficient than and tend
to lead the underlying assets markets. However, the spot prices of smaller and
less-frequently traded stocks may not be timely reflected in the futures market which
cause the lag effect and mispricing. As hedgers and speculators are trading in both
markets, their activities and information tend to be more fluid in the futures markets
than in the spot markets. Most empirical evidences support the lead effect more than the
lag effect. Finnerty and Park (1987) discover a significant lead-lag relationship between
futures and spot prices. Kawaller, Koch, and Koch (1987) find that futures contracts lead
the spot index by as much as 20 to 45 minutes while Herbst, McCormak, and West (1987)
observe that the S&P 500 and Value Line futures lead the spot index between 0 to 16
minutes. However, Laatsch and Schwartz (1988) find no lead-lag effect in the IMM.
Swinnerton, Curcio, and Bennett (1988) conclude that a lead time of 5 minutes is the best
predictor of the cash index with up to 30-minute range of predictability. Stoll and Whaley
(1990) find that futures prices lead spot prices on average of 5 minutes. Swinnerton,
Curcio, and Yonan (1995) note that Nikkei stock index futures do not lead the spot prices.
Chang, Jian, and Locke (1995) find the weekend lead effect on the S&P 500 futures
prices such that the Friday close to Monday open negative effect appears to be anticipated
in the last minutes of Friday's trading. They also extend the time frame of the weekend by
5 minutes at the close and open and find a doubling of the weekend effect.
-
- Evidence of Stock Index Futures Arbitrage
-
- MacKinlay and Ramaswamy (1988) find that arbitrage violations are path
dependent and it is less likely for the mispriced value to cross over to the opposite
arbitrage boundary. Merrick (1989) notes that the effective transaction costs are about
70% of the originally expected costs when unwindings and rollovers are used as part of a
complete arbitrage strategy. Daigler (1991) finds that arbitrage opportunities in futures
contracts are caused by the lag effect of the cash index. Chung (1991) concludes that the
size and number of mispricings are smaller than previously reported; arbitrage profits
have declined over time. Chan and Chung (1993) discover a higher intraday volatility is
followed by a decrease in the mispricing spread while an increase in the mispricing spread
is followed by an increase in market volatility. Yadev and Pope (1994) find significant
positive relationships between the magnitude of mispricing and the time to maturity and
conclude that mispricings are profit opportunities and not risk premia. Kumar and Seppi
(1994) observe that S&P 500 futures arbitrage has been less profitable gradually
because of the growth in the number of arbitrage desks, a reduced level of rebalancing
risk, and the greater cost of possessing information advantage over the market makers.
Swinnerton, Curcio, and Yonan (1995) notice that index arbitrage activity for the Nikkei
stock index futures has little impact on intraday price movements with the long arbitrage
effect greater than the short especially in the afternoon. Board and Sutcliffe (1996) find
that commodities listed in different markets have increased trading volume due to the
manipulations of market participants. The lower the rate of mispricings, the more
efficient the markets.
-
- Conclusion Back
to Top
-
- From the perspective of corporate users, forward and futures contracts
serve as their hedging tools to control or reduce their exposures to price risk and
returns volatility. Individual investors view these kinds of financial derivative as being
the vehicles for them to speculate or arbitrage in order to enhance their profits.
Speculators may find it more risky to take an uncovered position in either spot or futures
market, while arbitrageurs and calendar/cross spreaders are able to set up profitable
positions in both markets and combine them with appropriately leveraged positions more
effectively. No matter what the purposes and incentives are, all market participants
obtain more investment flexibility and latitude from parallel tradings in both futures and
spot markets than from naked transactions in the spot markets alone.
-
- The arbitrage-free principle allows the equilibrium relationship between
the futures and spot contract prices to hold. Arbitrage opportunities between the two
markets arise when either the futures or spot price is mispriced cross-sectionally. It is
also discovered empirically that futures prices sometimes lead spot prices within a shot
period of time. This also allows investors to determine the level of spot prices through
futures prices observation. There is one big precaution in the applications of financial
futures amidst today's sophisticated and high-speed trading markets of which investors and
firms should be aware. Since the relationship between futures and spot markets is normally
positive, the insurance protection against the down-side price risk when both markets
decline may lead to excessive net short positions and result in the market breakdown, as
occurred in major financial centers throughout the world in October 1987. These positive
implications and negative impacts are the products of the linkages between futures and
spot markets. All rest upon the rational judgements of market participants to employ sound
strategies to hedge against risks or enhance trading returns, and the proactive
intervention of market regulators to formulate prudent policies and implement appropriate
measures to stabilize the markets.
-
- The balance between the short and long positions in the aggregate
futures and spot contracts is of utmost importance to the healthy functioning of the two
markets. Too little supply of spot securities for future delivery will cause the futures
contract to be an ineffective hedging instrument. Too much heterogeneity among the supply
of the underlying assets tends to make the futures contract a bad long hedging vehicle.
Therefore, it is advisable that market participants trade futures contracts that are large
in deliverable supply and homogeneous in characteristics such as government securities and
foreign currencies.
References
-
- Board, J. and C. Sutcliffe (1996) The Dual Listing of Stock Index
Futures: Arbitrage, Spread Arbitrage, and Currency Risk, Journal of Futures Markets.
Buhler, W. and A. Kempt (1995) DAX Index Futures: Mispricing Arbitrage
in German Markets, Journal of Futures Markets.
Chan, K. and Y.P. Chung (1993) Intraday Relationships Among Index
Arbitrage, Spot and Futures Price Volatility, and Spot Market Volume: A Transactions Data
Test, Journal of Banking and Finance.
Chance, D.M. (1994) Futures Pricing and the Cost of Carry Under Price
Limits, Journal of Futures Markets.
Chang, E.C., P.C. Jain, and P.R. Locke (1995) Standard & Poor's 500
Index Futures Volatility and Price Changes around the New York Stock Exchange Close, Journal
of Business.
Chung, Y.P. (1991) A Transactions Data Test of Stock Index Futures
Market Efficiency and Index Arbitrage Profitability, Journal of Finance.
Cornell, B. (1995) Taxes and the Pricing of Stock Index Futures:
Empirical Results, Journal of Futures Markets.
Daigler, R.T. (1993) Financial Futures Markets, Harper-Collins.
Fabozzi, F.J. and F. Modigliani (1992) Capital Markets: Institutions
and Instruments, Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey.
Finnerty, J.E. and H.Y. Park (1987) Stock Index Futures: Does the Tail
Wag the Dog?, Financial Analysts Journal.
Herbst, A.F. J.P. McCormack, and E.N. West (1987) Investigations of
Lead-Lag Relationships Between Spot Stock Indices and Their Futures Contracts, Journal
of Futures Markets.
Hemler, M.L. and F.A. Longstaff (1991) General Equilibrium Stock Index
Futures Prices: Theory and Empirical Evidence, Journal of Financial and Quantitative
Analysis.
Houthakker, H.S. (1957) Can Speculators Forecast Prices?, Review of
Economics and Statistics.
Jarrow, R.J. and S. Turnbull (1996) Derivative Securities,
South-Western Publishing.
Kawaller, I. P. Koch, and T. Koch (1987) The Temporal Relationship
Between S&P 500 Futures and the S&P 500 Index, Journal of Finance.
Kolb, R.W. (1992) Is Normal Backwardation Normal?, Journal of
Futures Markets.
Kumar, P. and D.J. Seppi (1994) Information and Index Arbitrage, Journal
of Business.
Laatsch, F.E. and T.V. Schwartz (1988) Price Discovery and Risk
Transfer in Stock Index Cash and Futures Markets, Review of Futures Markets.
MacKinlay, C. and K. Ramaswamy (1988) Index Futures Arbitrage and the
Behavior of Stock Index Futures Prices, Review of Financial Studies.
Merrick, J. Jr. (1989) Early Unwindings and Rollovers of Stock Index
Futures Arbitrage Programs: Analysis and Implication for Predicting Expiration Day
Effects, Journal of Futures Markets.
Modest, D.M. and M. Sundaresan (1983) The Relationship Between Spot and
Futures Prices in Stock Index Futures Markets: Some Preliminary Evidence, Journal of
Futures Markets.
Murphy, A. and J.E. Hilliard (1989) An Investigation into the
Equilibrium Structure of the Commodity Futures Market Anomaly, Financial Review.
Saunders, E.M. Jr. and A. Mahajan (1988) An Empirical Examination of
Composite Stock Index Futures Pricing, Journal of Futures Markets.
Stoll, H.R. and R.E. Whaley (1993) Futures and Options: Theory and
Applications, South-Western Publishing.
Swinnerton, E. R.J. Curcio, and R.E. Bennett (1988) Index Arbitrage
Program Trading and the Prediction of Intraday Stock Price Change, Review of Futures
Markets.
Swinnerton, E. R.J. Curcio, and M.R. Yonan (1995) Index Arbitrage in
the Japanese Stock Market, Multinational Business Review.
Yadav, P.K. and P.F. Pope (1994) Stock Index Futures Mispricing: Profit
Opportunities or Risk Premia?, Journal of Banking and Finance.
* Worapot Ongkrutaraksa is a lecturer
in Finance and Strategic Management at Maejo University's Faculty of Agricultural
Business, Chiang Mai, Thailand. He used to conduct his post-graduate research in financial
economics at Kent State University and international political economy at Harvard
University through the Fulbright sponsorship between 1995 and 1998.
E-mail: worapot@iname.com
Home Page
|