|
Introduction The Keynesian and the monetarist views on how to conduct
national economic policy in both closed and open economies have inspired the policy-makers
in many post-World War II developed and developing countries for more than half a century.
Both views support the interventions by the public sector, i.e., the government and the
central bank, to plan for and manage the economy in order to take advantage over the
growth momentum of, while avoiding the negative impacts of market failure and external
shocks from, the economic and business cycles. Many Asian governments have been quite
successful in steering their open economies based on managed commercial and industrial
policies. Some, such as Japan and South Korea, even went further to integrate financial
policy into their overall national economic policy. These policy configurations work
effectively insofar as their economic performance, in terms of domestic productivity and
export capability, and their financial performance, in terms of domestic rates of return
on both riskless and risky assets, are persistently high relative to their trade
counterparts and the global market rates, respectively. However, when there exist the
imbalances between the two aspects of performance, policy tradeoffs, reprioritizing, and
periodic fine-tunings occur.
The economic and financial crises in Asia could also be explained from
the perspective of misalignment between the real and financial sectors. In this essay, I
would like to present my view on how a small open economy like Thailand can, in the medium
to long term, adjust her national economic policy orientation to become more in line with
the dynamics in the global financial markets environment, while taking into account the
conflicts and complements among policy goals upon domestic affairs as well as the behavior
of all market participants. The next section discusses conventional economic and financial
policy objectives, which the government and the central bank in general try to achieve,
and address some of their discords. Section three outlines the important impetuses that
occur in both domestic and international financial economies, which continue to exert
strong forces of change on national economic policy. In section four, I propose some
rationales and ways in which policy-makers can reorient their policy foci and revise their
interventionist roles in the course of major structural transition from the
centrally-managed economy into the fully-efficient market economy. Section five concludes
this essay.
Conventional Economic Policy
Policy-making in
a closed economy is typically geared toward attaining certain goals of aggregate
consumption and production in both real and financial economies. In the real sectors of
the economy, the objectives are to secure the satisfactory rates of employment and output
growth in the production sector while also having a commensurate stable price level and an
equitable income distribution in the consumption sector. These four policy targets (i.e.,
employment, output, price, and income), despite some tradeoff such as that of the Phillips
curve between employment and nominal price level, can be achieved when rational
expectations about inflation are dynamically built into the real economy (Friedman, 1967;
Lucas, 1976). Output or GNP growth and income distribution objectives, although hard to
reconcile in developing and emerging economies, can also be compatible through effective
schemes of taxation and some politically initiated fiscal spendings and subsidies.
On the financial side, two aspects of financial stability are sought:
1) interest rate stability and credit availability in financial intermediary sector, and
2) systemic stability and adequate liquidity in financial markets sector. Both financial
intermediaries and markets interact in the financial economy the same ways production and
consumption sectors do in the real economy. The financial aspects are even more crucial
than those in the real economy because of the fluidity of capital flows and the intense
competition between intermediaries and markets, which could easily destabilize the overall
financial system while also transmitting negative spillovers to the real economy and
contagion effects to other countries. With relatively stable levels of interest rates,
prudent and reliable financial institutions, and efficient financial markets, production
and consumption in the real economy can be effectively managed.
In an open economy, another aspect of financial stability is
imperative, i.e., an exchange rate stability. As more countries began to engage in
international trade and allow for capital flows, their goals to achieve interest and
exchange rates stability seem less feasible, especially with small countries that can by
no means affect the world economy. The conducts of fiscal and monetary policy in those
countries are therefore more difficult than those in the large and economically strong
countries like the U.S., Japan, and Germany. After the inception of the Euromarkets for
offshore Eurocurrency deposits and Eurobonds during the1960s and the demise of the Bretton
Woods System (i.e., the international regime of fixed exchange-rate parity) in early
1970s, interest rates and foreign exchange started to fluctuate widely on the
free-floating basis. To sterilize and immunize the effects of world interest-rate and
foreign exchange-rate volatility on their economies, small countries started to implement
more active policy programs in order to stabilize their domestic interest and exchange
rates. The success of these sterilization programs depends much on the concerted efforts
of the governments and the central banks to coordinate their fiscal and monetary policies
to achieve the overall economic goals.
When Thailand embarked on a series of National Economic and Social
Development Plans during the 1950s, the foci have been placed more on the real sectors
than on the financial sectors until more recently. Also in the real sectors, production
targets in terms of employment and output levels used to have held higher priority than
consumption goals in terms of price stability and income distribution. The private-sector
investments have been promoted through many developmental schemes from infant and senile
import-substitution industries to export-led ones. Industrial development has become the
main artery for national-income earners, especially toward the export markets. Market
interventions yielded spectacular payoffs to the country in terms of an annual GDP growth
range of 7-10% during the past two decades. However, this accomplishment came at the costs
to the consumption sectors when income disparity widened and inflation started to hike.
Export earnings that have accumulated as savings in the domestic financial system induced
banks and other financial services firms to lend heavily to many non-productive and
speculative (or nakedly-hedged) investments in real estate and capital markets. This
financial laxity after markets liberalization and institutional complacency has therefore
contributed to the destabilization of the country's financial system in the past years.
In essence, the conventional macroeconomic policy direction that
stresses high growth and wealth accumulation before welfare distribution puts more burdens
on the central bank to keep the balance between the real and financial sector pari passu.
It is, however, politically correct to argue that Thailand, during the last two decades,
should pursue such a policy direction. Yet, it is not advisable that the government should
carry on the same policy in the future without paying serious and adequate attention to
what have happened in the financial sectors and the consumption sector of the real
economy.
Impetuses of Change
The forces that
drive structural changes in financial markets and financial intermediaries come from
within and outside the country. In the domestic financial markets, two impetuses are being
materialized, i.e., disintermediation and markets liberalization. Disintermediation is the
process in which individual fund providers bypass financial intermediaries to supply funds
directly to borrowing firms or the production sector. This process is possible as
information and communications technologies are spontaneously developed to accommodate
market demands. The market for disintermediation is predominantly of commercial papers and
other structured short-and medium-term notes issued directly by the borrowers through
banks and finance companies. Markets liberalization involves provisions for trading of
those direct-financing instruments, other underlying securities and derivative products
both on and off the organized exchanges (e.g., over-the-counter (OTC) markets, and on-line
computerized trading systems) whereby transactions are subject to self-regulation, private
credit-rating, and market discipline, rather than to centralized regulatory agencies, as
well as for more foreign ownership and control in domestic financial institutions.
In the international markets, globalization and markets integration are
considered the common themes. Globalization of financial markets refers to the
coordination and standardization of trading rules and procedures, which allows more volume
of trading transactions to be made among different national markets with less spatial and
regulatory friction. A good example of globalized markets is the foreign exchange market
where transactions are made electronically among international banks, multinational
corporations, and individual currency dealers worldwide with a common language of trading
protocols. They virtually eliminate time-zone barriers by which continuous currency
tradings can be obstructed and distorted. As a result, foreign exchange trading volumes
have typically reached over $500 billion per day after 1990 in only three major markets
alone (London, New York, and Tokyo). Markets integration, on the other hand, is the
harmonization and merger of two or more national markets to overcome the discrepancies in
prices and transaction costs. One current example of markets integration, although
occurred in the U.S., is the merger between the NASDAQ dealer-type market and the AMEX
auction-type market. The market forces in both domestic and international levels not only
will drive out market inefficiency through transactions cost-reduction, but also
discipline the behavior and expectations of market participants through spatial and
intertemporal arbitrage continuous-trading activities.
For domestic financial intermediaries, financial engineering and
institutional deregulation have become more prevalent in recent years. In terms of
financial engineering, the intermediaries are competing - through the process of dynamic
trading of securities and derivatives - against each other based on how well they could
offer innovative products and provide unique services to their individual and corporate
customers. Coupled with markets liberalization in which foreign banks are allowed to
compete vis-a-vis domestic banks, many Thai financial intermediaries are hard pressed to
become ever more resilient in financial engineering activities. According to Merton
(1992), financial engineering can be undertaken in two modes: 1) underwriting mode and 2)
synthesizing mode. The intermediaries provide underwriting services to their clients in
order to increase their financial contracts' liquidity and creditworthiness in the
markets. Synthesized products (e.g., exotics and boutiques), on the other hand, are
specially designed to meet specific purposes of the intermediaries' customers who might
want to reduce their financial risks but do not intend to float their contractual claims
in the markets. The main benefit of synthetic financial engineering is that it prevents
other market participants from free-riding on the information advantages the client firms
generate and privately possess. This benefit, of course, has to be weighed against the
down-side risks of opacity and illiquidity the synthesized contracts have produced for the
holders.
The ongoing waves of financial deregulation in many countries are
intended to remove many outdated regulatory burdens that are the sources of inefficiency
in domestic financial institutions. In the U.S., for example, the activity firewalls under
the Glass-Steagall sections of the Banking Act of 1933 were finally repealed in the new
Financial Modernization and Financial Services Competition Act of 1997 to allow commercial
and investment banks to combine their operations. This bold move of the U.S. Congress
enable American banks to compete on the same level-playing field against foreign universal
banks that have long enjoyed the synergy of combined lending/synthesizing and underwriting
operations.
On the international level, financial intermediaries have evolved in
such a way that they become either multinational or transnational institutions (Michalet,
1984). Multinational financial institutions engage themselves in both retail and financial
services in the host-countries' financial systems. They are also subject to both home- and
host-countries' financial regulations depending upon their scope of activities.
Transnational financial institutions, on the other hand, do not operate in specific
host-countries markets, but establish their international financial centers to conduct
wholesale banking and offshore financing activities in the countries where there is the
least or no financial regulation, such as the Bahamas and Cayman Island. Their sources of
funds are mostly Euromarket-based. As Andrew Crockett (1997), the general manager of the
Bank for International Settlements (BIS), opines, the kinds of non-market force
appropriate to governing these new institutional arrangements are "regulatory
replications" that could mimic the market mechanism to discipline the intermediaries
in light of pervasive financial innovation and engineering. Thus, economics of regulation
and regulatory replications are becoming the highly active areas of current and future
research in financial and international economics, both in academic and professional
spheres.
Based on all the above immediate and potential impetuses, conducting
conventional economic policy will be more costly and less effective to accomplish some or
all of the desirable economic goals. The behavior of market participants has changed from
having limited choices of saving and investment to dealing with wider investment
alternatives vertically (across products and locations) and horizontally (over time and
maturities), or the combinations of both. The behavior of financial intermediaries also
changes from being functionally constrained in terms of activity firewalls and branching
limitations to becoming more flexible in financial innovation and more specialized in
financial engineering.
New Economic Policy
Given the fact
that international economic terrain is changing very rapidly and that domestic market
participants are also quickly responding and adapting to those changes, national economic
policy also needs reorientation and, if necessary, reform. The primary question that comes
to my mind is whether Thailand should be bothered adjusting her national economic policy
direction at all. If so, my secondary question is which policy goals should be
reprioritized and how? If not, what would be the counter-arguments against it? The keys to
address such questions, I believe, lie in the evaluation of domestic market participants,
whose preference might have changed from passive saving behavior to active investing
behavior due to 1) their increased wealth during the past years of economic growth, 2)
their optimistic and rational expectations about the strength of the country's economic
fundamentals fueled by the revolutionary advances in information and communication
technology, and 3) the liberalization of domestic financial markets, which allow these
changes in consumer/investor behavior to flourish.
There are several arguments for economic policy reforms in less
developed countries; most of which deal with commercial policy in order to change the
terms of trade using optimal tariffs (Stolper and Samuelson, 1941) or non-tariff measures
(Ray, 1988) and industrial or strategic trade policy to target for and subsidize the
winning industries (Krugman, 1986,1993). The effects and benefits of such policy reforms
are attributed toward the production sector of the real economy. My argument for policy
reorientation, however, is geared towards the consumption and financial economies. In
spite of the recent structural adjustments in Thailand, which make it unrealistic to claim
that Thai citizens would become more optimistic about the country's prospect, it is still
valid to conjecture that, with the right incentives coupled with awareness of undistorted
information, the trends toward optimism are quite promising. By contrast, the arguments
against any policy reorientation are that of 1) the political and institutional
status-quos, which are always the case when confronting reforms, 2) the strong interests
of industrial lobbyists and business pressure groups that try to preserve their
rent-generating turfs and rent-seeking privileges, and 3) the socio-psychological
challenges whereby the likelihood that the Thai people could successfully make their
transition from a passive saving society to an active investing society is minimal.
If my logical argument above sounds convincing enough, then it is quite
appropriate for Thailand to consider refocusing her economic objectives in response to the
dynamism in domestic and international financial markets environment and the changing
preferences in the Thai society. Two medium- to long-term policy goals that should be
focused in order to materialize this optimism are: 1) human capital development to provide
greater opportunities for Thai consumers and investors to become more sophisticated and
better-informed, which as a result would help promote price stability and sustain economic
growth; and 2) financial infrastructural development to allow intermediaries to perform
efficient economic functions by completing and perfecting the markets, which in turn would
enable Thailand to achieve the goal of systemic stability.
Distribution of Human-Capital Opportunities
What I mean by development of human capital and distribution of
opportunities is that, instead of overwhelmingly committing national resources to
accumulating wealth and physical capital in the production sector and focusing on income
distribution, Thailand can reallocate her domestic resources to enhancing human capital
and refocus on opportunity distribution. I had seen such a tendency toward this goal in
the Chuan administration during his first premiership, but unfortunately the momentum was
not carried on in the later governments. Investment in human capital includes more and
equitable accesses for Thai citizenry to: 1) advanced knowledge and technologies; 2)
productive activities and economic decision-makings; 3) political activities and public
choices; and 4) social activities and collective consumption alternatives and protections.
Increase in human-capital opportunities would yield many favorable
results to the Thai economy. First, improved knowledge-based domestic conditions and
continued transfer of new technologies would increase the number of highly-skilled Thai
workforces. As a consequence, employment growth target could be reached since market
demand for high-technology and service-oriented human resources is almost insatiable.
Second, better access to economic decision-makings for Thai citizenry would improve
labor-management relations thereby raising productivity, increasing the number of
risk-taking entrepreneurs who could spin-off to set up their own small businesses, and
resulting in more ethical corporate management practices. Third, ameliorated environment
for voicing public-policy concerns with less friction and censorship would increase direct
political participation by Thai voters and accountability of Thai politicians, which
altogether make the policy outcomes more responsive to citizen demands. And fourth, more
externally-motivated social networking activities would improve collective bargaining
power of Thai consumers, which could lead to an improvement in consumer protections and
choices both in terms of prices and quality of the products and services in the markets.
The implications of human-capital development are very important to
Thailand in that there will be more sophisticated and knowledgeable consumers who can
rationally map out risk-return payoffs from spatial and intertemporal consumption
opportunities, and better-informed investors who can make prudent investment decisions
based upon market prices and market signals as well as take proactive responses to
promptly correct market distortions.
Development of Financial Infrastructure
The policy goals of human-capital development and opportunity
distribution would not be truly effective unless there is also a simultaneous improvement
in the infrastructure of the Thai financial system. Financial infrastructure, as Merton
and Bodie (1993) put it, consists of the legal and accounting procedures, the organization
of trading and clearing facilities, and the regulatory structures that govern the
relations among the users of the financial system. The objectives of financial
infrastructural development are to help complete and perfect the markets. By completing
the markets, I mean a better allocation of risk-bearing opportunities among the Thai
market participants through the optimal holdings of the so-called Arrow-Debreu state
contingent claims (Arrow, 1964 and Debreu, 1959), i.e., the securities that have their
underlying and derivative quantity equal to the number of contingencies (states of nature)
in the entire markets so that every risk dimension can be mapped onto its corresponding
return. With domestic markets approaching completion, transaction costs and risks are
substantially reduced, which after all would benefit both consumers and investors as well
as the firms in various industries. In terms of perfecting the markets, I refer to a
reduction in information gaps between the better-informed agents and the less-informed
principals in the markets through signaling, screening, and disclosure to resolve the
problems of adverse selection and moral hazard. Once the markets are nearly perfect,
information and agency costs decrease, which in turn stimulate more economic transactions
based upon rational expectations of the Thai investors.
Financial markets can be made more complete by two methods: 1)
financial engineering to unbundle and reallocate economic and financial risks for
different risk preferences of market participants; and 2) financial innovation to
efficiently share and redistribute those risks within and across the markets. Without
adequate and appropriate financial regulation and supervision, financial engineering
activities would prove to create more harm than good in the sense that most synthetic
financial contracts are opaque and illiquid, which in effect increase systemic risk.
Financial innovation cannot be efficiently spiraled down to the markets unless there exist
appropriate trading and clearing organizations (i.e., market microstructure) to support
it. Both methods for market completion are therefore vital to and necessary for the health
and stability of domestic financial system. They would readily support the trends in
disintermediation and liberalization in the financial markets as well as those that
currently occur in financial intermediaries.
The ways in which markets can be more perfect are through: 1) financial
signaling based on risk accounting, and 2) financial disclosure based on market-value
accounting. These involve the improvement in legal and accounting procedures to handle
risk and market-value accounting as well as the establishment of self-regulatory
organizations and credit-rating agencies as the watchdogs to monitor both signaling and
disclosure of financial intermediaries and exchange institutions. Today, accounting
standards are being revised worldwide to accommodate for risk management and address
differential information issues. Many banks have adopted value-at-risk (VaR) systems for
their internal control purposes (Jorion, 1997). The BIS also came up with the revised
Basle Accord in 1993 to tie banks' capital bases to both credit and market risk indexes
calculated from the standard VaR model. At the same time, the U.S. Federal Reserve System
had initiated similar framework to allow banks to pre-commit their capital to their
potential risk-taking lending and investment activities. Still, there remain some other
risk dimensions, such as operational and regulatory risks, that require more research
attention and further practical treatments.
Conclusion
Amidst the
changing international financial scenes and their impacts on domestic economic activities,
Thailand should consider reorienting her economic policy objectives. The past four decades
have witnessed the commitment of national economic and social policy to economic
development and growth in the production sector of Thailand's real economy with impressive
performance. But such a track record has been achieved at the expense of the country's
consumption and financial sectors in which income disparity and financial vulnerability
still persist. The thrusts for structural change shook the country unprecedentedly during
1997, which exposed Thailand to a great economic difficulty, as a result of financial and
currency crises. It is now an appropriate time for the policy-makers to ponder as to
whether or not Thailand should adapt herself in order to reemerge as a more competitive
country in the global marketplace.
It is my personal conviction that there are still rooms for Thailand to
reshape herself through some adjustments in national economic policy. As the forces of
change are most explicit in the consumption sector and the financial system, the new
policy goals should be stressed on such issues like human capital and financial
infrastructural development. The benefits from this long-term economic policy
reorientation are in terms of the country's smooth transition from being a society of
passive savers to the one with more active and prudent investors, supported by a strong
and efficient market-oriented financial economy, which is more allocationally complete and
informationally perfect. It is expected that, over the long horizon, Thailand will be
better able to cope with internal instability and withstand external shocks that are both
directly and indirectly impinged upon the country.
References
Arrow, K. (1964). The Role of Securities
in the Optimal Allocation of Risk-bearing. Review of Economics Studies, 31,
91-96.
Crockett, A. (1997). The Changing Role of Central Banks. Proceedings of the
Money Macro and Finance Annual Conference, Durham, NC, USA.
Debreu, G. (1959). Theory of Value. New Heaven: Yale University Press.
Friedman, M. (1968). The Role of Monetary Policy. American Economic Review, 58,
1-17.
Jorion, P. (1997). Value at Risk: The New Benchmark for Controlling Derivatives
Risk. New York: McGraw-Hill.
Krugman, P.R. (1986). Strategic Trade Policy and the New International Economics.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Krugman, P.R. (1993). The Current Case
for Industrial Policy. In Dominick Salvatore (Ed.), Protectionism and World
Welfare. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Lucas, R. (1976). Economic Policy Evaluation: A Critique. In Karl Brunner and
Allen H. Meltzer (Eds.), The Phillips Curve and Labor Markets. Carnegie-Rochester
Conference Series on Public Policy, 1, 19-46.
Merton, R.C. (1992). Operation and Regulation in Financial Intermediation: A
Functional Perspective (Working Paper No. 93-020). Boston, MA: Harvard University,
Graduate School of Business Administration.
Merton, R.C. and Z. Bodie (1995). Financial Infrastructure and Public Policy. In
Dwight B. Crane et al., The Global Financial System: A Functional Perspective (pp.263-282).
Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press
Michalet, D.G.E.C. (1984). International Banks and Financial Markets in Developing
Countries. Paris: Development Center of the OECD.
Ray, E.J. (1988). Changing Patterns of Protectionism: The Fall in Tariffs and the
Rise in Non-Tariff Barriers. In Jeffry A. Frieden and David A. Lake (Eds.), International
Political Economy: Perspectives on Global Power and Wealth (pp.353-367). New York: St.
Martin's Press.
Stolper, W.F. and P.A. Samuelson (1941). Protection and Real Wages. Review of
Economic Studies (November), 58-73.
Back to Top
About the Author
* Worapot Ongkrutaraksa is a lecturer in
Finance and Strategic Management at Maejo University's Faculty of Agricultural Business,
Chiang Mai, Thailand. He used to conduct his post-graduate research in financial economics
at Kent State University and international political economy at Harvard University through
the Fulbright sponsorship between 1995 and 1998.
E-mail: worapot@starmail.com
Home
Page |