Navigation
Papers by Melberg
Elster Page
Ph.D work

About this web
Why?
Who am I?
Recommended
Statistics
Mail me
Subscribe
Search papers
List of titles only
Categorised titles

General Themes
Ph.D. in progress
Economics
Russia
Political Theory
Statistics/Econometrics
Various papers

The Questions
Ph.D Work
Introduction
Cost-Benefit
Statistical Problems
Social Interaction
Centralization vs. Decentralization

Economics
Define economics!
Models, Formalism
Fluctuations, Crisis
Psychology

Statistics
Econometrics

Review of textbooks

Belief formation
Inifinite regress
Rationality

Russia
Collapse of Communism
Political Culture
Reviews

Political Science
State Intervention
Justice/Rights/Paternalism
Nationalism/Ethnic Violence

Various
Yearly reviews

Philosophy
Explanation=?
Methodology

 


[Note for bibliographic reference: Melberg, Hans O. (1993), Sovietology: Why the totalitarian model is the best, http://www.oocities.org/hmelberg/papers/931001.htm]
[Comments: This paper was written in 1993, while I was an undergraduate. Today I do not agree with all the arguments, nor the way they are expressed. Nevertheless, this was probably the essay for which I did the most reading. I also feel that the main views are still sound. Lastly, I am still interested in the subject so I would like to receive comments. On this background I feel confident enough to make it available on the Net.]



Sovietology: Why the totalitarian model is the best

This essay will argue that the attempts to classify and interpret the Soviet system in terms of a concept is valuable because it focuses the debate on distinguishing the significant from the less significant factors in the political system. The value of a concept 1 thus depends on its success in focusing on the central features of the system. By using this criteria for the value of a concept, the essay will argue that the totalitarian model is the most helpful in understanding events in the Soviet Union because it focuses on the lack of adaptability caused by the fusion of politics and economics in a centralised ideological structure. That is not to say that other concepts are unhelpful, for example a historical-cultural view is also valuable to understand the central features of the Soviet system. However, other concepts, such as corporatism and pluralism, are less helpful since they focus on the adaptability of the system, not its rigidities.

The value of a concept and the definition of a system's central feature depends on the aim of the researcher. If the aim is to find concepts that "facilitates comparison across different political-economic systems" 2 , as Bunce and Echols argue, then the central features of the Soviet system will tend to be those which are comparable to the Western system, for example, the influence of various groups. If, on the other hand, the interest of the researcher is to "locate the causal factors, the changes which affect all other parts of the system", as Daniel Bell proposes, then the importance of variables is determined by their causal strength. Hence, a useful concept in this perspective must capture the causally important factors. A third perspective to judge the significance of features and hence the value of a concept, is the effect on individual life (liberty, scope of action), as implicitly suggested by Schapiro.3 The question is then by which arguments one can say that the totalitarian concept and no other concept a) best captures the aim of research and b) best captures the central features of the system as defined by the aim of our research.4

The ultimate aim of research in the social sciences cannot be proved logically, but it seems intuitively correct to say that the aim is to improve the quality of life for individuals (some important factors: income, freedom, justice, peace, stability). The ultimate value of a concept is then given by its ability to locate the dynamics of the causal factors which affect the quality of life for the people in that system.

In what way does totalitarianism capture and fulfil the aim of our research? There are many definitions of totalitarianism, but the essence of all the definitions is the attempt to establish "total control" over all spheres of life in order to create a new society. As Schapiro writes:

Totalitarianism is "a form of personalised rule by a leader and an elite who seeks to dominate both society and the regular legal structure which is called the 'state'"5

Implicit in this definition is the attempt to fuse economics and politics and the consequent elimination of the division between the personal and the public sphere of life. This is implicit because to gain total control the elite cannot allow rival institutions such as the church influence over moral standards or free trade unions to control the workers. Most important it cannot leave the individuals with the private property because they would then have the economic resources to reject state control. Thus, the totalitarian concept points out that the quality of life, at least with respect to individual autonomy, liberty and political influence, is poor under totalitarian rule. The main cause of this is the fusion of economics and politics under a centralised elite. All this is validated by empirical evidence about the quality of life in the Soviet system. Hence, the totalitarian concept fulfils the requirement that a concept should capture the most important features affecting the individual quality of life.

Moreover the totalitarian model is not a static concept, as some critics claim. It is fully compatible with changes in the system over time. For example, the economic growth after Stalin and in the beginning of the Brezhnev period was precisely caused by the fusion of economics and politics. It was this fusion which made possible the mobilisation of enough resources to create extensive growth because the state could force people to work. The totalitarian model can also explain the decline of economic growth and the failures to reform the system. Extensive growth cannot go on forever since resources are scarce and the totalitarian political system is not compatible with significant intensive economic growth. This is so because the subordination of economics under politics destroys the market mechanism which are vital to economic efficiency. When prices do not reflect the real scarcity of goods, scarce resources may be sold cheaply, thus encouraging waste. In theory the planners should be able to correct this, but what Hayek called "information-overload" made it impossible. The system was simply too complex to be planned in detail. In this way the totalitarian model contains both predictions about economic growth and decline by focusing on the effects of the fusion between economics and politics. This make the totalitarian concept very helpful to an understanding of the Soviet Union from Stalin to 1985.

The intrinsic irreformability 6 of the Soviet system is also predicted by the totalitarian model. As Brzezinski argues, the failure of Khrushchev's reforms and his downfall in october 1964 exemplifies how the essential properties of the system (in his opinion the political autonomy of the monopolistic party-state) could prevent reform.7 The failure of the Kosygin economic reforms of 1965 further add to the evidence of the basic irreformability of the Soviet system. The fundamental reason why it was irreformable was that the fusion between economics and politics was inherent to the ideology of the regime and hence the justification of Communist rule. The central insight of Marxist analysis was that private ownership of the means of production is the basic problem of capitalism since it causes alienation and also constitute an inefficient way to organise production (the relations of production do not correspond to the productive forces). Consequently the most important change in a society moving towards Communism would be the public ownership of the means of production i.e. political control over the economy. So structural economic liberalisation (diffusion) was necessary for economic growth, but impossible because the basic legitimacy of the regime rested on the fusion of economics and politics. This made the system intrinsically irreformable. 8 Once again this shows the central insight of the totalitarian concept in identifying elite dominance in all spheres of life as the characteristic causal feature of the system.

One suggested problem for the totalitarian conception, is its inability to explain the desire for reform in the first place. If the central feature of the system is an elite using total domination as a tool for constructing their ideal, why would there be reforms which even tried to distribute power, such as Khrushchev's distribution of power to regions or Brezhnev's "trust in cadres" which gave the regional party secretaries much more power and security. There are several ways of explaining this within the totalitarian model. Martin Malia suggests in his concept of "The New T-model" that there was a rhythm of alteration between relaxation and the building of Communism. This was caused by the need for breathing spaces to collect resources to build communism, exemplified by the NEP period under Lenin. In my view the key is to view the Soviet system not as being fully totalitarian, but as an attempt to use total control to create Communism. This explains why there was what T.H. Rigby calls a shadow culture of fresh ideas when the Soviet Union collapsed in 1991. Neither society nor the elite were completely monolithic because this is obviously impossible. But the important fact was that unanimity was the ideal. Pluralism of values was by definition evil inheritance from old class antagonism.

On the basis of the arguments so far it is clear what was wrong with many of the other concepts of the Soviet system. Concepts like corporatism and pluralism was of little value and of little help in understanding the system since they focused their attention on the wrong issue. What Amann calls Group B theories mistakenly focused on the indicators of change and adaptability, not the signs of continuity and stagnation. The following example shows in more detail how Group B theories failed and hence why they are of little value.9 

One model which intends to describe the whole Soviet system is Valerie Bunce's concept of corporatism. This is defined by him as:

"a decision-making structure in which major functional interests groups are incorporated into the policy process by the state and its leaders."10

The evidence for making this the central feature of the Soviet system, under Brezhnev is taken to be the rising supply of consumer goods, the increased emphasis on consulting "experts" and "scientific management", the low rates of turnover in important positions and the stability of the budget allocations over time. Using the concept of corporatism Bunce argues that "...consensus, co-optation and co-operation were the essential characteristics of developed socialism." 11 By the criterion used in this essay this is, to put it mildly, misleading and hence the concept is of little value.

The totalitarian concept is misleading because it mistakenly gives prominence to the indicators of adaptation (responsiveness from pressures from below), while the real essence of the system was the continuity of rigidities. This is implicitly conceded by Bunce when he contradicts himself in two different articles. In the first he argues that "the study of Soviet politics is first and foremost the study of eras, periods associated with specific leaders doing specific things"12 In other words he argues that there is no one Soviet system, but, as A. Meyer writes and Bunce quotes, "a succession of political systems..." 13 In a later article, still defending the corporatist concept, Bunce writes that "the policy process during Brezhnev's time, as during the Khrushchev and Stalin periods, was shaped by the fusion between political and economic realms in the Soviet system."14 This is inconsistent because the first quote says that the essential features of the Brezhnev period were unique to his era, while the second quote makes the defining features of the system under Brezhnev common to the period of other Soviet rulers. Hence, the ambiguity in judging the central feature of the Soviet system is another weakness in the corporatist concept.

The only other main concept which is of any value, except for the totalitarian approach, is the historical cultural approach as R. Tucker rightly argues. This concept is valuable because it helps explaining central features such as the lack of distinction between a private and a public sphere (Byzantine, not Roman law); the Russian attitudes to time (long term view), authority (Asiatic), and work (storming); and how generational change may influence politics (new values - attempted reforms). Lack of space prevents a closer elaboration on these issues, but the point is that the explanatory power of the historical cultural approach gives it value, though it lacks the ability to make a clear distinction between more or less significant features.

In conclusion it may seem that the arguments in this essay about the value of totalitarian concept presents an over-deterministic view of history, as Alexander Dallin warns against in his article. But: how can it be over-deterministic to say that an attempt to try to do the impossible is bound to fail? This essay has argued that the essence of the Soviet system, as defined by the totalitarian model - the attempt to build Communism by fusing everything into politics - was bound to fail because of the breakdown of efficient allocation of resources. Would it be over-deterministic to say that humans cannot fly like birds? By this I do not mean that everything in the Soviet system had to happen as it did. There is room for detailed variations, but from a structural point of view the system was doomed to fail.

Ybarra: "The totalitarian model endured as long as it did ... because it tried to answer the right question: how did such a police state survive and flourish?" 15


NOTES
1. In this context only the value of general concepts are discussed, not concepts that aim at describing details of the system.

2. Bunce and Echols, p. 2

3. "For the Soviet citizen the ruler-ruled relationship is therefore the only one which retains any meaning or validity in determining his life, his liberty, and his scope of action." (Scapiro, p. 118)

4 It should be noted that there is no necessary connection between the value of a concept and its ability to capture the essence of a system. As Alex Inkles suggests a concept may have value because it opens unexplored perspectives which, if examined closer, will increase our knowledge.

5. Schapiro, p. 102

6. J. Kirkpatrick

7. Breslauer, p. 215

8.The events after 1985 is outside the scope of this essay, but the failure of these reforms give further weight to the totalitarian view that the system was irreformable and had to collapse.

9. One important qualification must be made here. Very few people defended the concept of pluralism and other Group B concepts as a characterisations of the central feature of the system. Rather they though about their concepts as additions to the existing models of totalitarianism which they viewed as unable to cope with the changing details of the Soviet system. So not everyone in the Group B category can be accused of using the wrong concept to describe the whole of the Soviet system, since this was not the intention behind their concepts. 10. Bunce and Echols, p. 3

11. Bunce, p 135

12. Bunce and Echols, p. 1

13. Bunce and Echols, p.1

14. Bunce, p. 131

15. p. 222 (article?)


BIBLIOGRAPHY
Almond, Gabriel A. (1990), A discipline divided: Schools and sects in political science, Newbury Park: Sage Publications

Amann, Ronald (1986), Searching for an Appropriate Concept of Soviet Politics: The Politics of Hesitant Modernization? British Journal of Political Science, 16(4):475-494

Amann, Ronald Amann (1990), Soviet Politics in the Gorbachev Era: The end of Hesitant Modernization, British Journal of Political Science 20:289-310

Breslauer, George (1992), In defense of sovietology, Post-Soviet Affairs 8(3):197-238

Bunce, Valerie (1983), The political economy of the Brezhnev era: The rise and fall of corporatism, British Journal of Political Science 13:129-158

Bunce, V. and Echols, J., Pluralism or Corporatism, in Kelly D. R. (1980), ed., Soviet politics in the Brezhnev era, New York: Praeger Publisher

Burrowes, Robert (19??), Totalitarianism: The revised standard version (Review of H. Arendt: The origins of totalitarianism and C. J. Friedrich and Z. Brzezinsky: Totalitarian dictatorship and Autocracy (2nd. ed), World Politics, ???

Dallin, Alexander (1992), Causes of the collapse of the USSR, Post-Soviet Affairs 8(4):279-302

Hough, Jerry F. (1977), The Soviet Union and Social Science Theory, Harvard: Harvard University Press

Malia, Martin (1992), From Under the Rubble, What?, Problems of Communism 41:89-106

Remington, Thomas F. (1992), Sovietology and System stability, Post-Soviet Affairs 8(3):239-269

Schapiro, Leonard (1972), Totalitarianism, London: Pall Mall

Skilling G. and Griffiths, Interest Groups in Soviet Politics

Solomon, Susan G. (1983), Pluralism in the Soviet Union, London: Macmillan

Tucker, Robert C. (1992), Sovietology and Russian History, Post-Soviet Affairs 8(3):175-196



[Note for bibliographic reference: Melberg, Hans O. (1993), Sovietology: Why the totalitarian model is the best, http://www.oocities.org/hmelberg/papers/931001.htm]