Transportation costs and spatial integration of
agricultural commodity markets in
By
Edward Mabaya
Introduction
·
A key argument of Chapter II and VI of the
“Transport and the Millennium Development goals in Africa” working document is
that efficient operation of transport infrastructure will contribute towards eradication of extreme
poverty and of hunger (MDG 1) and enhance international cooperation in support
of economic development (MDG 8).
·
An implicit assumption behind this premise is
that reduced transport costs will increase spatial market integrations, allowing
for specialization within and across countries thereby maximizing benefits from
trade.
·
This paper evaluates the potential impacts from
reduced transportation costs on intra- and inter-country integration of agricultural commodities markets.
Background
·
As part of the Structural Adjustment Programs
(SAP) introduced in the late 1980s and early 1990s, most African governments
relinquished their control on agricultural markets to the "invisible
hand" of market forces. Implicit
in the deregulation of agricultural markets was the assumption that, when left
to themselves, markets would converge toward a competitive market equilibrium in
which gains from trade are maximized.
·
Because agricultural production is highly
specialized across both space and time, and the commodities are bulky and often
highly perishable, the degree of relationship between pairs of markets across
space, time and form is key to appraising the economic performance of
agricultural markets.
·
Inter-market
transfer costs consist mainly of loading and unloading costs, transportation,
and the traders’ normal profit, applicable taxes, financing costs and
risk. Of these, transportation costs usually
constitute the largest share.
Market Integration, Competitive Equilibrium and
Social Efficiency
·
Market
integration is defined as the transfer of excess demand from one market
to another, manifest in the physical flow of commodities (tradability) and/or
the transmission of price shocks from one market to another (contestability).
·
Competitive
equilibrium, on the other hand, refers to the state in which the
marginal profits from arbitrage equal zero.
If markets are in competitive equilibrium, opportunities for profitable
arbitrage cannot exist at the margin.
Thus, for competitive spatial equilibrium, price differentials for an
identical good between any pair of spatially distinct markets should be less
than or equal to the cost of transferring the good between them (with equality
if trade occurs).
·
Social
Efficiency: Both market
integration and competitive
equilibrium treat inter-market transfer costs as exogenous. To maximize the social benefits from
specialization and trade, inter-market transfer costs should be minimized, all
trade restrictions abolished, and market failures corrected. Thus, to attain “social efficiency of
product allocation across markets depends fundamentally on the minimization of
the costs of commerce” (Barrett, 2001).
It is this last concept, social efficiency, that development oriented
spatial market analysis study should seek to evaluate and public policy makers
should aim for. However, because inter-market
transfer costs are difficult to observe and measure, spatial market integration
is often used as a proxy measure.
Eradication of extreme poverty and of hunger
(MDG 1)
·
Chapter II of the “Transport and the Millennium
Development goals in
·
With more than 70% of
·
Examples are given in the working paper on the
impacts of transport infrastructure on growth patterns. High transportation costs result in segmented
spatial equilibrium or isolation for both input and output markets within most
a most African countries.
·
Segmented
input markets imply that productivity enhancing agricultural technology
such as fertilizer and improved seed does not reach farmers in remote areas. There is strong empirical evidence supporting
the link between farmer’s access to an all-weather road access to technology adotion (Zavale, 2005; Croppenstedt
and Mulat, 1996). Improved road infrastructure places
agricultural technologies closer to the farmers
at affordable prices.
·
For output
markets, segmented equilibrium implies that comparative advantages in
agricultural productivity are not fully exploited and farmers are forced to
pursue food security through self sufficiency. Without integration, no
mechanism exists for price signals to be transmitted from food deficit to food
surplus areas, prices may become volatile, and producers may fail to specialize
according to comparative advantage (Baulch 1997).
·
Numerous studies have been conducted to
investigate spatial integration and efficiency of spatially distinct domestic
markets for agricultural commodities: Dercon
(1995) analyzed the integration of teff markets in post-war Ethiopia; Goletti
and Babu (1994) also used cointegration in the analysis of maize markets in
Malawi; Alderman
(1993) also used the model Ravallion model to test for integration among food
markets in Ghana; Fafchamps and Gavian (1995) used a combination of integration
and efficiency techniques, including the PBM to test for market integration and
efficient spatial arbitrage in livestock markets in Niger.
·
Current evidence from formal markets in the most
African countries suggests that intra-country market integration of cereals is
yet to be attained (Jayne et al 2005, Traub et al 2004, Mabaya 2003,
Mutambatsere 2002, Abdula 2005, Barrett 1997).
More recent studies that incorporate inter-market transfer costs in
analyzing market integration and spatial equilibrium have found most markets to
be in segmented equilibrium due to high transportation costs.
·
Inter-market
transfer costs for agricultural commodities between domestic markets in most
African countries are extremely high due to poor road infrastructure and limited
modes of transportation. Traders still
rely heavily on public buses, probably the least efficient way of transporting
bulky and often perishable agricultural commodities. .
Despite the tremendous potential for short term profits in arbitraging
between markets, there are very few privately owned trucks available for
providing such services (Mabaya, 2002).
International cooperation in support of economic
development (MDG 8)
·
Chapter VI of the “Transport and the Millennium
Development goals in Africa” working document highlights the “special needs” of
·
Empirical evidence throughout the developing world
shows that key factors in poor economic performance of landlocked countries are
“high transport costs and the inadequacy of transport and communication
infrastructure”.
·
The high elasticity of trade volumes with
respect to transport costs support the argument that transportation costs are a
major barrier to trade, and thus specialization, by Africa’s land locked
countries.
·
Improving intra-regional trade, through
reduction of tariff and non-tariff measures has been widely advocated for as a
critical piece in the food insecurity puzzle (SADC FANR 2003, World Bank DTIS,
Mozambique 2004, Malawi 2002, Tschirley et al 2004, Mano 2003, Arlindo and
Tschirley 2003, Moepeng 2003).
·
There is significant trading in agricultural
commodities among SADC countries at both the formal and informal trade levels,
with a country like
·
Within regions, countries with markets that are
more open experience more trade and faster market responses to shocks.
(Tschirley et al 2004)
·
High transportation costs favor “high-value low
volume” products in regional trade, thereby sidelining development of the
agricultural sector whose products are often “low-value high-volume”.
·
The higher perishability of agricultural
commodities also amplifies the impact of “slow and cumbersome boarder-crossing
procedures”. This additional risk faced
by traders of agricultural products is often not factored into trade and
integration analysis that often assume equal per-unit inter-market transfer
costs for food products and manufactured goods.
Conclusion
·
The extent to which the benefits expected
through greater market openness will be realized, depends significantly on how
well integrated and efficient the markets are, both within and across borders
(Ndlela 2002, Lewis 2002, Wobst 2002, Arndt 2005, World Bank 2002 and 2004).
·
Studies that evaluate market integration and
spatial equilibrium for both domestic and regional markets should pay closer
attention to the size and seasonal variance of transportation costs.
·
In deciding priorities for investment in road
infrastructure, priority should be given to road networks that link high
agricultural potential areas to food deficit regions. Market integration and spatial equilibrium
studies can be used to guide these priorities.
·
To maximize benefits from improved road and
transport infrastructure, parallel investments have to be made in the following
complimentary areas: market information systems, standardization of grades,
contract enforcement, access to finance, and better coordination of market
institutions.
·
Given that central role of agriculture in rural
development in
References
Arndt,
C. ‘The
Barrett,
C.B., Li, J.R. ‘Distinguishing Between Equilibrium and Integration in Spatial
Price Analysis’. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics, Volume 84, pp292-307, May 2002.
Barrett,
C.B. ‘Measuring Integration and Efficiency in International Agricultural
Markets’. Review of Agricultural
Economics, Volume 23 Number 1, pp19-32, 2001.
Baulch, B.J. ‘Testing for Food Market Integration
Revisited’. Journal of Development
Studies, pp512-534, April 1997.
Dercon, S.
"On Market Integration and Liberalisation: Method and Application to
Erero, J.L.,
van Heerden, J. ‘The Role of Freight Rates in the Race between Road and Rail in
Fafchamps,
M.,l and Gavian, S., “The Spatial Integration of Livestock Markets in
FEWS-NET,
WFP. ‘Informal Cross Border Trade in
Goletti,
Francesco and Suresh Babu, 1994, Market Liberalization and Integration of Maize
Markets in
Jayne,
T.S., B. Zulu, D. Mather, E. Mghenyi, E. Chirwa, and D. Tschirley. Maize Marketing and Trade Policy in a
Pro-Poor Agricultural Growth Strategy: Insights from Household Surveys in
Eastern and Southern
Jayne,
T.S. , Makumbu, M., Jones, S. and Jiriyengwa, S. ‘Maize Marketing and Pricing Policy in
Eastern and
Lewis,
J.D. ‘Reform and Opportunity: The Changing Role and Patterns of Trade in
Mabaya,
E. ‘Smallholder agricultural markets in
Mano,
R. ‘The food Security Situation in the
SADC Region: Policy Dimensions and Scope for Recovery.’ FANRPAN, Policy Discussion Paper No. 1,
2003.
Mutambatsere,
E. “Regional Trade and Food Security in
Southern Africa: Comparative Advantage, Welfare And Market Efficiency”
Ndlela,
D. ‘Determinants of Exports from SADC and the role of market access.’ Trade and Industrial Policy Strategies
(TIPS) Annual Forum, 2002.
Traub,
L.N., Jayne, T.S., ‘The Effects of Market Reform on Maize Marketing Margins in
Tschirley,
D., J. Nijhoff, P. Arlindo, B. Mwinga, M.T. Weber, and T.S. Jayne. ‘Anticipating and Responding to Drought
Emergencies in