THE GENESIS OF CAPITALIST DECADENCE

 

 

The real domination of capital, technology-driven mass production, became prevalent only in the 20th century (and continues its development to this day). But the transition towards it accelerated, especially in the second half of the 19th century. In the industrializing world, the proportion of the labor force employed in agriculture dropped from 3/4 in 1850 to 1/3 in 1900. By 1870, the most developed countries suffered overcapacity (even though many sectors were still not mechanized and most industrial workers were still craftsmen working in small shops). Crisis and years of deflation followed. In Britain, the leading industrial nation, prices fell 44% between 1873 and 1895. This undercut the incentive for M-C, for investment in the domestic industry: from 1873 to 1913, the rate of productivity growth in Britain was zero. Instead, British capital financed the industrialization of other countries, where the average organic composition of capital was lower and the rate of profit therefore higher, which yielded Britain interests which more than compensated for its negative trade balance and low domestic rate of profit. Other countries followed this example and stepped up their foreign lending when their industrialization reached a plateau, thereby fostering the horizontal spread of capitalist development.

 

The crisis of the 1870’s also ended free trade. The scale-enhancement of production and the decreasing cost of transportation had greatly reduced the natural protection local markets enjoyed before. The temptation to blame foreign imports for market saturation was irresistible. Walls of tariffs were erected, behind which, as Engels put it, a war for industrial supremacy was being prepared. Some of the protectionist measures were clearly counter-productive; with various tariff wars the capitalist class shot itself in the foot. Others however, enabled countries such as Germany and US to develop the strongest industries in the world. Their accumulation was facilitated by the influx of foreign capital and fed by the metabolism between the conditions of formal domination (low organic composition, low productivity but a high rate of profit) and the newly emerging giant industries, which raked in surplus-profits thanks to their competitive advantage on their large internal markets.

 

There were several more crisis moments before the turn of the century but the early part of the 20th century saw a real ‘sturm und drang period in which real domination rapidly spread, aided by a series of technological breakthroughs (the combustion engine, chemistry, electricity etc). Every period of fast technological change is characterized by accelerating productivity (and thus increasing material wealth) and huge surplus-profits for the strongest, most innovating capitals, because new cost-saving technology creates new competitive advantages and the rapid pace in which new products are introduced constantly creates temporary opportunities for monopoly-profits. But then as now, these characteristics were hiding the exacerbation of the underlying basic contradictions. The boom was further stimulated by the intensification of exploitation made possible by the new industrial methods (Taylorism was introduced in 1895 and quickly spread). But meanwhile, an important escape-valve was in the process of being closed. Despite protectionism, the development of scale and productivity had greatly stimulated international trade. In 1913, foreign trade per capita was more than 25 times greater than in 1800. At the eve of world war I, the world economy was more integrated than it ever was or would be again until the aftermath of world war II. As a result, since the end of the 19th century, competition established for the first time uniform prices for most commodities traded on the world market. Before that point, the market values of most commodities were determined by local conditions of production only. A low organic composition of capital yielded a high rate of profit and an even higher one for developed capitals exporting more cheaply made commodities which could be sold above their value, at the local market value. No wonder that their export rose much faster than their production. But they had to absorb the costs of transportation and tariffs. Such obstacles did not hamper financial capital, so its export was even more profitable and grew even faster, mobilizing productive forces abroad and fostering horizontal development. But after competition enforced uniform world market prices and thus established international values, the market value for an increasing number of commodities was no longer determined by local conditions but by (average) international conditions. That means that those capitals which produced these commodities cheaper (under their international value) still obtained a surplus-profit but those who produced them with more backward, labor-intensive methods (above their international value) lost part of their surplus-value to their competitors. As we explained elsewhere, because of the tendential equalisation of the rate of profit within nations, this loss was shared by their entire economy. As a result, the lower organic composition of capital of the less developed country, instead of yielding a higher than average rate of profit, yielded a lower one, the more that market values were determined by international trade. This sharply reduced the incentive for developed capital to invest in the industrialization of others and thus also reduced the tendency for capitalism to develop horizontally.

 

The first part of the 20th century was also a period of tremendous acceleration of the concentration of capital. Uncounted small companies went bankrupt, were taken over or merged. It was the time of birth of the giant companies (Ford, General Motors, General Electric, BASF, Siemens, Daimler-Benz etc) which still dominate today. Up to that point, the domestic market sufficed for most capitals. but now industrial forces outgrew them. Despite the increase in international trade, overcapacity was building and the rate of profit fell. To defend the most developed industries, cartels were formed and other measures were taken to restrict production and to prevent prices from falling. But inevitably capitalism was moving towards the point at which the shortage of productive demand and the fall of the rate of profit would compel it to massive devalorization. Before that point was reached however, war intervened.

 

The moment at which the progress of real domination fundamentally changed the conditions of accumulation for global capital is hard to pinpoint. But it is certain that such a change took place, whichever term is used to describe it, that  massive devalorization became an intrinsic part of the accumulation process, that therefore the continuation of capitalism imposed on society increasingly brutal violence and self-destruction and thus placed before the working class the need to fight, not to improve its conditions of exploitation within capitalism, but to overthrow it. That’s why we consider 1914 as the starting date of capitalist decadence. In the remaining part of the century, war would make more casualties than in the entire preceding human history. It is true that amidst this endemic destruction, capitalism continued to develop and to grow, that real domination continued to deepen and spread, and that the resulting technification continued to stimulate productivity and thus also the quantity and quality of use-values, even for the working class. Those who think that the conditions for revolution require the irreversible stagnation of capitalism and abject poverty for the vast majority of the working class will wait forever. They have not understood that an irreversibly stagnating capitalism is an oxymoron, that crisis and productivity growth do not exclude each other, that capital seeks higher productivity to fight its crisis, yet worsens it this way, that the struggle of the working class is not one of variable capital reacting only against its own demobilization but of the part of humanity which, because of its place in the production process, is most capable both of recognizing the mortal danger that capitalism represents for humanity and of eliminating it.

 

The onset of decadence cannot be explained as inevitably imposed at that point in time by the objective state of the economy. The case can be made that, if the capitalist class would have recognized the counter-productive effect of its protectionist policies and would have retracted them, the capitalist system would have entered its phase of massive destruction considerably later. And if the capitalist class would not have clung to the gold standard or to balanced-budget dogma, if it would have embraced Keynesianism much earlier and used the monetary and fiscal levers that were potentially there, then for much longer still .…. But as the saying goes, with ‘ifs’ you can put Paris in a bottle. The understanding of the capitalist class of its own situation and possibilities (and the weight of the past upon it) is a material force that impacts the course of history. We reject vulgar Marxism’s mechanistic infrastructure-superstructure deterministic causal relation that reduces consciousness or the lack of it to a mere passive, reflective factor and thereby fails to understand history.

 

Sander