Chapter 2

Sunk costs: costs that were previously invested and that are nonrefundable

Honoring sunk costs: behaving as if the nonrefundable expense is equivalent to a current investment
   Violates the first criterion of rationality: decision should only be based on future consequences

Best way to avoid sunk costs is to start from the present and look to the future
Probabilities can be assessed properly only with reference to future events
   Gambler's fallacy: when events are independent you shouldn't take the past into account
      People expect chance sequences to be locally representative of chance, whereas the true probability comes out only over an infinite amount of trials
   It's different to assess the probability of an entire pattern and that of an independent event given past events

Law of small numbers: incorrectly assume that a small sample is as representative of the general population as a large sample
   Chance is not self-correcting; it just dilutes high scores with scores closer to the average

It is harder not to honor sunk costs if other are involved
   Reputation and self-concepts may play a role

Children and non-human animals are less prone to honoring sunk costs
   We have a tendency to consciously overgeneralize rules and to be limited by our conscious capacity to handle information
   Automatic processes may be able to handle more information at one time

To avoid traps:
   Set limit in advance whenever it's possible
   Use limits as a time to reassess whether withdrawal or persistence is wiser, independently of prior investment; it must be the result of future-oriented cost-benefit analysis