[NY BOOKS REVIEW] The International Crisis: An Interview GEORGE SOROS and JEFF MADRICK |
January 14, 1999 |
In July of 1997, the currency of Thailand, the baht, fell precipitously in value when the government abolished the link it had long maintained to the US dollar. The fall in the value of currency spread to other nations in Asia, including Singapore, Taiwan, Malaysia, the Philippines, Indonesia, South Korea, and Indonesia. As this happened, there was a dramatic outflow of capital from these nations. Investors generally feared that Asian companies would no longer be able to meet the enormous volume of their debt obligations denominated in US dollars and other foreign currencies. The financial turmoil threatened even such economic powers as Hong Kong and China. Thus a financial crisis began in Asia whose consequences are still being felt as far away as Russia and Brazil. Many of the affected nations are now suffering from a full-fledged depression, with widespread unemployment, rapidly expanding poverty, and, in some cases, social unrest. Some experts believe the advanced economies of Western nations may also deteriorate largely as a result of the international turmoil. As one of the world's most successful hedge fund managers, George Soros has long been involved in global capital movements. He came to widespread public attention when his fund sold an estimated $10 billion worth of British pounds short in 1992 in anticipation that the currency would soon have to be devalued. He netted a profit of $1 billion in a matter of weeks. In 1996 and 1997, Soros's fund, and similar hedge funds, had also been betting heavily that overvalued currencies such as the Thai baht and the Malaysian ringgit would soon fall. These hedge fund managers were accused of causing the ensuing crisis. Soros in particular was singled out by Prime Minister Mahathir Mohammed of Malaysia as the source of his nation's problems. In fact, Soros had given up the daily management of his hedge funds in 1989 to devote himself to philanthropic activities and to writing about the world economy. His charitable efforts include the financing of foundations in thirty-one countries dedicated to what he calls an "open society," based on the ideas of his former teacher, the philosopher Karl Popper. To Soros, an open society is essentially a constitutional democracy that protects liberties, such as those made explicit in America's Declaration of Independence. Soros has spent hundreds of millions of dollars through his foundations, which have conducted a variety of economic, educational, and humanitarian activities, including, for example, providing water and electricity in Sarajevo during the Bosnian war and the setting up of a new European university in Budapest. He has recently turned more of his attention to America's problems, sponsoring projects on drug use and on how Americans view death. Soros has been widely praised for his imaginative generosity but he has also been criticized for participating in the affairs of governments while also trying to make profitable investments. In December, Soros published a new book, The Crisis of Global Capitalism, in which he writes that what he calls "market fundamentalism" may be "a greater threat to open society than totalitarian government today." Soros proposes more regulation of markets as well as the establishment of a global agency to help reduce market instability around the world. We discussed the current financial crisis and his proposed remedies in two conversations we had in December. J.M. Jeff Madrick: The collapse of the Thai currency, the baht, in July 1997 was the immediate cause of the global financial crisis. I know that you had been selling the baht many months before the decline. Why? George Soros: The trouble could be seen six to nine months before the decline actually occurred. Thailand's trade deficit was very high, and it had to be offset by an enormous inflow of capital. The amounts of money required were expanding rapidly. We could anticipate that. But what we couldn't anticipate was the magnitude of the consequences. JM: When the link of the baht to the dollar was broken, international investors fled. GS: I don't think it was so much the speculators attacking the Thai currency at the outset. There were a large number of private loans to Thai borrowers in foreign currencies. A lot of people in Thailand had borrowed in foreign currencies, converted into the Thai currency, and invested the money or lent it out for real estate development and other investments. Investors assumed that the relationship to the dollar would be stable. But suddenly, when the baht collapsed, those dollar obligations became enormous and debtors had to run for cover. They sold the baht and bought dollars. A company like Siam Cement, the best company in Thailand, took a currency loss that not only wiped out all its earnings but a large part of its equity as well. So, naturally, since this happened to many companies, the stocks fell also. It was a combination of a currency, stock market, and banking crisis. One element reinforced the other. The debtors depressed the local currency, the fall caused losses, which then reinforced the decline in the stock market. The banks were now loaded down with bad debts. JM: How did the fall of the baht affect the other nations of the region? GS: Once the link with the dollar was broken, the Indonesian and Malaysian currencies fell as well. The decline was contagious and spread to Taiwan, the Philippines, and Singapore. It built up to a speculative attack on the Hong Kong dollar. Korea was temporarily insulated because it had some form of capital controls. But the Korean and Japanese banks were heavily involved in Indonesia. They couldn't renew the loans they had made there, and this eventually caused the problems in Korea. JM: Many critics now say that excessive lending on the part of the major Japanese, American, and European banks was the principal problem. Obviously, local business couldn't have borrowed so freely unless the money was readily available at attractively low interest rates. Do you agree? GS: That was certainly a common element. JM: Wasn't it the main problem? GS: I would hesitate to say it was the sole cause. There were some differences among these nations. For example, Malaysia's borrowing was mostly internal, not international. Indonesia was really not overindebted. Their trouble was that they had borrowed from the Korean and Japanese banks which now wanted to get their money back because of their own troubles and troubles elsewhere. I am more familiar with the Korean situation than with some of the others. The chaebol, the big Korean conglomerates, had debt-to-equity ratios of four to one. This was wholly unacceptable by international standards. And they were operating with very low profit margins. Their earnings covered their debt service, mostly interest costs, only 1.3 times. Once problems started, the banks had good reason to worry whether these companies could repay their debt. So it was the interconnections among the various countriesthrough international markets and through the banksthat turned it into a widespread crisis. JM: One of the longstanding controversies involving yourself and other hedge fund investors is that you sell an enormous amount of the currencies when you think they are high. But this puts pressure on the currencies to be devalued, forcing the nations to spend a lot of their reserves to buy their currency in an attempt to hold it up. What of the claim that the baht would have been able to hold its value if you and other investors had not sold short in such great volume? GS: No, I don't think that's right. This is something that had to happen, irrespective of whether we took a position or not. As a matter of fact, though we were in the market early, we were not selling the baht for six months before the collapse. There may have been others who were attacking the currency in July. But we were not. Actually, we were buyers of these currencies during the decline because we didn't expect them to go down as far as they did. For instance, when the Indonesian rupiah fell from 2,400 to the dollar to about 4,000, we thought it was too low. So we bought it. It immediately proceeded to fall to 16,000 to the dollar. That was not a pleasant experience for us. But at the time we were actually a balancing factor rather than a reinforcing one. It shows that speculators can lose money. JM: In England, you are still highly criticized in some circles for having been the most active seller of the pound in 1992. They say you drove it down, costing British taxpayers billions. Your defenders, such as the financier Leon Levy, claim the British government had overspent their reserves to maintain the pound at insupportably high levels. This made their exports too expensive and weakened their economy. So the fall in the pound only helped the British economy. I take it you also believe the pound would have fallen, anyway. GS: Yes. It would have fallen whether I was born or not. So I think our position was completely defensible. I believe markets are amoral. The problem is that they are not always stable. They frequently swing to excesses. That's why I say that markets, instead of swinging like a pendulum, can sometimes act like a wrecking ball, knocking over economies. In the Asian collapse, the interesting thing is that the crisis there varied from country to country. You can identify some similarities. But none of the causes was present in all the countries. Some had too much debt. Others had weak banks. So there has to be a unifying theme and that was the international financial system itself. JM: There has rarely been a more vivid example of the interconnectedness of the international financial system than the recent crisis. I think most commentators thought the Asia crisis would be contained. GS: I did not think it necessarily would because I was quite familiar with the situation in Russia. I could see the financial connections that were linking, for instance, Indonesia to Korea because Korean banks had invested rather heavily in Indonesia. Then when Korea got into trouble, the Korean banks had to withdraw considerable funds from Russia and Ukraine. That contributed to the crisis in Russia. And the Brazilian banks had invested rather heavily in Russian treasury bills, which got one of the Brazilian investment banks into trouble, so there was a resulting tremor in Brazil. JM: What was the immediate cause of the Russian collapse in late August of this year? GS: The government was unable to collect taxes. This was a longstanding, chronic situation. It financed its expenditures by issuing ruble-denominated treasury bills. As the situation got riskier, the interest it had to pay went higher. In the end, it had to pay 100 percent per year. This was untenable. The International Monetary Fund came in with a program that was inadequate because it assumed that the Russian government could roll over its treasury billsthat those who owned them would just buy again and again when they came due. But the domestic banks that held much of this debt became insolvent because the value of the treasury bills fell as interest rates rose, and the bank's investments in stocks also fell. They could not keep buying more bills. With the Asian crisis, foreign banks were not about to buy more of these bills. They, too, were selling. It was a full-fledged banking crisis. JM: You believe the shortfall could have been met by a concerted action by the more prosperous members of the international community. GS: The shortfall was $7 billion. If it had been made up, it would have enabled the government to pay out the maturing bills until the end of the year. It was then late summer. During that time, the government officials could have shown whether or not they were able to collect taxes. And if they were able to, then the market conditions would have improved and the crisis would have been resolved. JM: But those were serious unknowns. I think outside sources must have feared that they would be throwing good money after bad. GS: Yes. But I think making up the shortfall would have been a reasonable calculated risk. Russia under Prime Minister Kierenko actually had the best, most determined reform government that it had had since the collapse of the Soviet Union. But it had to deal with the fact that enormous economic power in Russia was held by the groups that can accurately be called robber capitalists. And it's exactly because the government officials were trying to collect taxes from them that they went out of their way to destroy the government. JM: You say in your new book that a major investment you made in Russia was the worst of your professional career. You participated in a syndicate which bid for and won the Russian telephone company, Svyazinvest. Why did you make the investment? You had long resisted investing in nations in which you had charitable foundations. One of your most active was in Russia. GS: It was a very difficult decision. I got involved because I was, in effect, betting the government was making the transition from robber capitalism to legitimate capitalism. Had the government succeeded, it would have been a very rewarding investment. As it turned out, the sale provoked a fight among the oligarchs, as the powerful business leaders there are called. Before this, they more or less staged rigged auctions of state businesses, with one syndicate or another taking over through hidden arrangements. This time, from all appearances, we had a real auction. When competitors like me showed up, however, this caused a lot of problems; the old arrangements were threatened. So the oligarchs brought the Anatoly Chubais government down. JM: How did they do this? GS: For one thing, they controlled the press. So there was a tremendous campaign against Chubais. And Chubais, it was disclosed, had taken $90,000 in payment from one of the oligarchs for a nonexistent book. Remember, the same oligarchs had gotten Chubais to run Yeltsin's political campaign. It's typical of such mafia-type action that you want your associates to have dirty hands, so you can use it against them if you have to. It turned out that the oligarch with whose syndicate I was working also bought a book from a minister. So the auction I participated in was not necessarily as clean as I thought it was. JM: Would you make the investment again? GS: No. I was combining two considerations. A political onewhich was to help to transform the economy into legitimate capitalism. And a financial onewhich was to make a profit. Obviously, they didn't combine well. When the Russian economy collapsed, we took a big loss. JM: The crisis was at last brought home to America in the late summer soon after the Russian collapse. The large hedge fund Long-Term Capital Management almost went bankrupt. It was eventually saved by the intervention of the New York Federal Reserve Bank, which organized a rescue by private investors, who invested over three billion dollars in the company and took it over. What precisely occurred?1 GS: When the markets were shaken by the Russian situation, a lot of the normal relationships between different markets were thrown offsay, the relationship between the prices of corporate bonds and Treasury bonds. When these relationships get out of line, they can be a profitable opportunity because eventually they can be expected to return to normal. But this time they didn't return to normal, or they didn't soon enough. The analytical system that Long-Term Capital Management used to exploit such opportunities works, let's say, 99.9 percent of the time. But because they had borrowed so heavily, that very unusual deviation of the markets, which might occur 0.1 percent of the time, caused them almost to run out of capital. JM: The problems at Long-Term Capital Management nearly brought down a lot of other financial institutions. The banks that had loaned them money lost hundreds of millions of dollars. GS: If Long-Term Capital had been forced to liquidate, the deviations from the normal behavior of bonds and other investments would have been even greater and the effects on the banks would have been even worse. That is why the New York Federal Reserve intervened. One really interesting thing is that it showed how faulty are the methods used by banks to assess and manage risks. JM: You believe that the Asian economies could have been stabilized much earlier and the crisis there minimized. Did the International Monetary Fund make matters worse, as many observers, including the World Bank, now argue? They imposed harsh restrictions on these countries when they lent them more money. GS: Well, let's remember that under the present system, the IMF is not in a position to intervene before a crisis develops. According to its mandate, it is there as a lending facility that countries can turn to in times of emergency. But the IMF officials can't turn to a country and say, "You are a bad boy and misbehaving and you have to change your policies." Now they could, in the future, issue reports in which they could point out that these countries are following bad policies. This would frighten international investors into more circumspect lending policies. Such a suggestion has now been put before the IMF. But it is not without its own drawbacks. The fact is that these countries often try to deceive the IMF. If the reports were going to be made public, they would have an even greater incentive to hide the facts. JM: But I am a little surprised you are treating the IMF so tolerantly. Even given their mandate to stabilize currencies, they attached very strict requirements to the money they were lending to the Asian nations. Interest rates soared in these countries as a result, business ground to a halt, and these countries were thrust into severe recession. GS: The IMF was worried that if they didn't raise interest rates, the currencies would fall even more. To stabilize a currency, they insist on raising interest rates so that capital will not flee abroad. Or if it flees, it will have to pay a very heavy cost in the lost high interest rates. Then when a recession occurs as a result of high interest rates, the people can't afford to buy foreign goods and imports fall. The country then generates a trade surplus and currency is now on balance coming in. That is how the IMF figures the country will again be able to pay its debt service and start rebuilding the economy. JM: At the price of a steep and humanly cruel recession, and perhaps political turmoil. As many as twenty-five million people have sunk into dire poverty in Indonesia and Thailand. Social unrest is on the rise. | 1 On this question, see the interview with Leon Levy in The New York Review, December 18, 1998. (back) |
Reformatted for mugajava website.
For any comments send e-mail to mugajava@oocities.com
Visit http://www.oocities.org/Eureka/Concourse/8751/