Militant, for struggle, solidarity and socialism

Below is the first of a series of articles based upon the introductions and conclusions to the main political discussions at the CWI's 1996 European School by members of the CWI Secretariat, and reproduced in "The Future for Socialism" as a contribution to discussion within the workers movement.

Comments are welcomed

Worldwide:

the Challenge of Globalisation

The working class faces an entirely new international situation since the collapse of the former Stalinist regimes. It has posed many challenges for Marxists concerning the nature of capitalism and the new tasks which the working class has to confront.

By Tony Saunols, International Secretariat of the CWI

One of the most important questions is: "Is capitalism entering a new and higher stage of its development?" The extreme proponents of the ideas of globalisation answer this question in the affirmative. They defend the idea that through the development of massive transnational companies the limitations of the nation state have been overcome. This, they argue, will open a new historical period of capitalist development.

The CWl must answer these arguments if we are to be able to offer a correct analysis of the nature of the present epoch. Such ideas have their origin on the one hand in the excess of confidence which gripped the ruling class internationally after the collapse of the old Stalinist regimes in 1989-90, and on the other in important changes in the world economy.

In 1993, the World Congress of the CWI characterised the economic phase of capitalism since the mitd-1970's as one of depression within which there has/will be particular conjunctures of growth There have been clear trends which vindicate this analysis There are four important economic features which have clearly emerged in the recent period.

  1. The emergence of structural mass unemployment and social polarisation in the industrialised capitalist countries.
  2. Growing social/economic polarisation within the industrialised countries.
  3. Increased domination of the former colonial world by the imperialist powers.
  4. Increased social polarisation and poverty within the former colonial countries.

Th. Core' of the arguments concerning globalisation can be summed up as follows Firstly the recent period has seen the development of a globalised economy which is now dominated by the emergence of major transnational corporations which have broken free from national boundaries and developed a kind of "super-imperialism". Secondly with the development of a more open and integrated market the perspective is now raised for the former colonial countries to be integrated into the industrialised capitalist economies Thirdly the general idea is put forward that the freedom of the labour market will prove to be the great "equaliser" between rich and poor Fourthly, all this is made possible because of the alleged death of the socialist alternative and the collapse of the majority of the planned economies after 1989. To sum it up as Business Week commented in one of its editorials a few months ago "A new and brutally competitive world economic order is emerging with the demise of the Cold War. The fundamental force behind this New Order is the transnational corporations and the integration into the global economy of the new capitalist nations and much of the developing world representing some 3000 million people.

It is the acceptance of these ideas which provides the justification for the swing to the right and the acceptance of the market by the leaders of the former workers' parties These ideas have been used in the recent period as an ideological weapon against the working class There has been an attempt to try to sap the confidence of the working class as it has moved into struggle to protect itself against the economic offensive which has been launched on an international scale by capitalism.

Supporters of globalisation theories present the 1990s as a decade of the global market place where job relocation is an unstoppable process, rendering futile any resistance by the working class. The CWI has two central tasks before it: the first is to answer these ideas and to clarify exactly what changes have taken place over the recent period. Secondly, the CWI and its sections has a decisive role to play in propagating the ideas of socialism among the most advanced workers and youth. The credibility of socialism as an alternative to the domination of the market needs reconquering internationally.

If these tasks are to be achieved Marxists must take account of important changes which have taken place in the world economy. There can be no doubt that it has become more internationalised. The flows of capital and development of world trade have reached new levels. With the development and greater monopolisation of the multinational corporations there has been a clear tendency to internationalise production. Products can be designed in one continent, assembled in another and sold around the globe. This process has taken place not only amongst the multinationals of the industrialised capitalist countries. It has also affected some of the secondary imperialist powers and some of the emerging capitalist powers as well. South Korean car companies now import and assemble cars in Botswana to sell them in South Africa at 70 per cent of the price of other cars assembled there.

The most striking feature of the world today is the increased pressure and the dominance of the world market. This means that it is even less possible for one country to opt out from the world market and the broader political processes which are taking place. It is reflected in a growing uniformity of bourgeois policy and programme on a world scale. This has gone side by side with a substantial fragmentation of the political institutions and parties of capitalism. This domination of the world economy has decisive political implications. The influence of the world market currently determines the policies pursued in each country. No country has been able to escape its influence. It has been one factor which has prevented the implementation of reformist policies. This is likely to be the case in the short to medium term.

In recognising the internationalisation of the world economy we must also distinguish between what is fact and what is myth, but presented as fact by the proponents of globalisation. There are 37,000 multinational companies (MNC s) at present. They have 170,000 subsidiaries in different countries, controlling just over one-third of the world's private assets. This marked tendency towards monopolisation and internationalisation of the world economy, together with the massive development of foreign trade and the expansion of international capital flows, is not a basis from which a new and distinct period of capitalist development can take place. The main features which have recently developed have been manifested at different times in the history of capitalism.

Whilst the world economy has undoubtedly developed and internationalised recently it is not any more open today than it was between 1870 and 1914. This then gave way luring the 1930 s to a period of protectionism The introduction of new techniques of production and communication is a quantitative development, rather than a qualitative new stage in the development of capitalism. In some industries it has gone further than in others, particularly in chemicals, communications and car production But one of the myths that must he shattered is the idea that the world economy is currently dominated by transnational corporations which no longer have a national basis, and that consequently all the limitations of the national state have been overcome. This must be demonstrated by the fact that of the 37,000 MNCs, 70 per cent were home based in 14 OECD countries.

It is true that some companies have been able to establish genuine transnational enterprises which span the globe. There has been a certain tendency in this direction. This has been mainly concentrated among European firms, especially Dutch companies. However, genuine transnational corporations at this stage are generally the exception rather than the rule. Most have a definite national or at most a regional base. In the USA, the parent organisations of the multinational corporations based there have 78 per cent of total assets, 70 per cent of total sales and 70 per cent of their total employment force at home. Of the top 5000 multinational companies internationally, two-thirds of their sales are either based in the country of origin or in the region where they operate. This clearly points to the fact that the vast majority of the multinational companies, despite the internationalisation of production techniques still tend to be nationally based.

It is more accurate to say that the most dominant tendency has been the development of regionalisation, rather than real globalisation. This development of regionalisation is one factor which is reflected in the emergence of regional trading blocks such as the EU, NAFTA MERCOSUR, ASEAN, etc.

The one aspect of the economy where it is possible to say that a real process of globalisation has taken place is in the financial markets.

However, the decisive feature is the dominance of the world market. This has rendered the application of distinct and separate policies within national boundaries impossible for any length of time. This is especially the case for policies of a reformist or left reformist character. Take, for example, the position of Mitterrand s government in the 1980s in France. It initially tried to move against the general international trend, adopting a more clearly reformist, or Keynesian based policy, but was forced in a matter of months to abandon it. As the chairman of CitiCorp pointed out: "There are 200,000 monetarists in trading rooms all over the world. They conduct a kind of global plebiscite on monetary and fiscal policies of government. There is no way one nation can opt out.- And referring to Mitterrand, he commented: The market took one look at his policies and within six months, the flight of capital forced him to reverse course."

This was dramatically seen in Venezuela which has experienced two attempted coups, mass rioting against the IMF austerity package which left hundreds dead, and the election in 1994 of a populist left wing coalition led by Caldera. This government has on two occasions attempted to move in the direction of more state intervention, control of oil prices, and other measures based on reformist policies. On both occasions, Caldera was forced to abandon these measures and adopt the neoliberal measures demanded by the IMF and the World Bank. As the World Bank stated in relation to Caldera's change in policy, "He does not believe in it, he does not want it, but he has no choice but to implement it."

These examples illustrate the domination of the world economy and show that the material basis which allowed capitalism to implement lasting reforms in the post Second World War decades no longer exists. Temporary concessions may be given by a government threatened with massive social explosions. However, they will rapidly be taken away again because of the limitations of the resources of capitalism.

In recent years there has been much greater social inequality on a global scale. This can be seen both geographically and socially. The gap between rich and poor nations has widened. The same process has occurred between the wealthy and the downtrodden within countries. The strangulation of the former colonial world by the imperialist powers has tightened. Any limited development which has resulted from investment due to internationalised production techniques and the introduction of new technology has been concentrated in relatively few areas. As a result it has only benefited a tiny minority of the population. This has taken place in the former colonial world at the same time as greater social polarisation, between the rich and poor. in the advanced capitalist world and even the major imperialist powers.

The increase in exploitation in the former colonial countries is one of the most important aspects of the economic processes which have occurred. This is graphically illustrated if we look at world trade. Trade between the industrialised countries was $2044 billion a year in 1994. Among the other countries of the world it was a mere $195 billion during the same period. The expansion of world trade was the main driving force in the boom in the world economy which took place in the post-Second World War period.

Today the increase in Foreign Direct Investment (FDI) is pointed to as the new motor force which will open up a new historical period of capitalist development. It is heralded by right-wing economists as the salvation which will allow the former colonial world (or at least sections of it) to develop. FDI did expand dramatically, especially between 1983 -1990. (During this period FDI grew by 34 per cent per annum compared with global merchandise trade which grew by 9 per cent.). This prospect is wholly false. The increase in FDI which has taken place is extremely uneven and not comparable with the massive expansion in world trade which took place during the post war decades. 75 per cent of FDI is concentrated into what is called the triad of the US, Europe and Japan. This accounts for a mere 14 per cent of the world s population. A closer study of FDI reveals an even more devastating situation. If the quantity of investment into the ten most important developing countries is added together it means that 43 per cent of the world population is in receipt of 91.5 per cent of FDI flows.

Even this does not reveal the full picture. Included in these figures are FDI flows into China. Most investment there is concentrated into the coastal provinces, particularly in the south. If these eight provinces plus Beijing are separated out and China is divided into two ( between recipients of FDI and non-recipients) a recalculation shows that 91 per cent of total FDI goes into countries and regions which only make up 28 per enl of the world s population! The vast majority of humanity is gaining absolutely nothing from this process.

The nature of FDI also gives an indication of how it will affect long term economic development. It is largely made up of short/ medium-term loans and speculation, and buying up privatised companies. This has particularly been the nature of FDI going into the former colonial world.

The Asian Tigers are used as an example to be followed in the rest of the former colonial world. The impressive growth rates in Singapore, Hong Kong, South Korea and Taiwan have been presented as an illustration of what is possible. Developments in these countries have been quite exceptional and impressive economic growth has been achieved. In general this has taken place over quite a prolonged period. These countries have been transformed becoming overwhelmingly urbanised and industrialised. There are two features which stand out. On the one side, the growth and development of these economies has been based on the adoption of precisely the opposite economic policies which are now being applied globally. It has largely been the consequence of state intervention, particularly the use of joint private and public funds together. This was the case in South Korea, where special arrangements were arrived at in relation to trade with the US. Growth has been on the basis of these policies and not the adoption of the open, free market, noninterventionist policies which are currently demanded by the World Bank and the IMF.

However, the very development of these economies has brought its own contradictions. It is one thing to be able to sustain this growth as the economies have been developing. It is an entirely different question to sustain that growth after the economies have passed through a period of development. There has been a lot of publicity referring to wage levels in these countries reaching the lower levels of wages earned by workers in the main imperialist countries. This recent development will mean a loss of the advantage that these countries had in offering cheap labour! The recent upheavals and strikes in South Korea are an indication of how the very development of these countries has also created a much stronger industrial working class. Over the next few years the struggles of workers in these countries will be an important feature of events in that region.

The increased development (economically and socially) of each of these countries together with the emergence of capitalist China will also result in heightened conflicts in this area because of the increased strength of the national bourgeoisie in these countries and the inevitable struggle for markets which is developing.

The economic trends within the Tigers have been the exception rather than the rule when compared with the processes which have taken place in the former colonial world. It is worth noting that in the 60's, Brazil was pointed to as the new model to be followed. There are many differences between the situation in Brazil and South Korea. However, despite any differences both have seen new conflicts and upheavals. The very developments that have taken place will result in heightened regional conflicts and also pose the necessity for the ruling lasses in these countries to increase the exploitation of the very young and new working class which is being created.

The emergence of regional trading blocs has demonstrated the two contradictory features present at the moment. On the one side, there has been a clear tendency for the economies within trading blocs to be pulled together. This reflects the internationalisation of the economy which has taken place. At the same time as they have been pulled together, new conflicts have developed within them which have served to pull in the opposite direction. This process has unfolded at differing rhythms and varying degrees in each trading bloc. The European Union has seen the most powerful tendency towards integration. In others such as MERCOSUR or ASEAN it has been much less developed.

In Europe the process has gone a long way but it has thrown up contradictory tendencies and conflicts between different European countries. However, one important feature is that the very steps required to fulfil the Maastricht criteria for EMU (reducing the state deficit to 3 per cent of GDP) threaten to create new problems. In order to fulfil the criteria, Germany threatens to pull the whole of Europe into recession.

In some of the other trading blocs the same contradictory tendencies are at work as well. NAFTA, at the time when Canada and Mexico joined, was projected as a great success. The perspective originally put forward by the US ruling class was that it would evolve into a trading bloc which covered both North and South America. The developments of NAFTA were paralleled in South America with the formation of MERCOSUR. However, with the establishment of these regional blocs new contradictions rapidly began to emerge and the limitations of these agreements were exposed.

Most dramatically, the crisis in Mexico compelled US imperialism to intervene in 1994 and bail out the Mexican ruling class to the tune of billions of dollars. This has had repercussions throughout the rest of the continent, beyond the immediate shock waves which swept the financial markets. Chile is viewed as the Latin American Tiger, and the next entrant into NAFTA. The Chilean ruling class looked towards NAFTA and the East and spurned MERCOSUR. After the crisis in Mexico, the US has been far more cautious about rapidly expanding NAFTA south of the .Mexican border. Whilst Chile continues to negotiate with NAFTA, its membership has been constantly delayed by the USA. Chile itself has become less enthusiastic about immediate entry to NAFTA and has now opted to join MERCOSUR as an associate member.

Problems within NAFTA have been mirrored by heightened frictions within MERCOSUR, which is dominated by the powerful Brazilian economy A conflict of economic interest has clearly emerged between Argentina and Brazil. The former is threatened with a flood of imports from the latter. At the same time Argentina has a different agenda for MERCOSUR than Brazil. Argentina has viewed it as a step towards eventual entry into NAFTA and a unified trading bloc being established throughout the Americas. Brazil looks to consolidating a South American trading bloc which it would dominate, existing alongside NAFTA.

The developments in these trading blocs illustrate the tendencies towards internationalisation in the world economy and also the new contradictions and conflicts of interest which are arising. Whilst the dominant trend has been in the direction of internationalisation of the world economy and the dropping of trade barriers wilt this continue indefinitely? Can these recent trends prevent a return to any form of protectionism and state intervention?

Elements of protectionism have continued during this period on a small scale, and in a disguised form. This has usually been done either through currency devaluation or subsidies. A change in the economic situation could force a change in policy and a return to .some protectionist measures. This could arise especially in the context of mass social upheavals and explosions and with the onset of a slump in the world economy. It is true that any return to protectionist measures may be more likely to be implemented on a regional basis rather than a national one because of the process of internationalisation of the economy which has already taken place.

The regional frictions which have developed have coincided with imperialism having to confront the new world situation which has developed post-1989. In the recent period there have been two main aspects to the policy adopted.

Firstly, despite its relative economic decline over recent years the USA has still tried to assert its international role. It has been extremely cautious in terms of moving towards direct military intervention and where this has been done, it has been done under the auspices of the United Nations.

Secondly, the main offensive by US imperialism has been political or diplomatic rather than military. In this respect it has been quite hesitant. In the Middle East Clinton conducted an open campaign to try and secure the re-election of Peres in order to try and keep the peace process on track. This policy was then repeated in an even more strident fashion in the Russian Presidential elections. The intervention by all the Western powers to try and secure Yeltsin's re-election was almost unprecedented in its brazenness.

Since the last international meeting of the CWI all the much-heralded "peace processes" have run into increasing difficulties and problems. This shows the limits of imperialism's ability to resolve such conflicts. The defeat of Peres in the Israeli elections (in May 1996) is certain to place increased strains on the peace agreement and result in further instability in the region.

Recent US policy has been linked to the forth-coming elections in the US. This has certainly been demonstrated in relation to Cuba, through the introduction of the Helms/Burton Bill. (This enables the USA to take sanctions against any company - including non-US firms which invest in Cuba). This has been directed at trying to bring the regime down and humiliate Castro. It is done with an eye to securing the Cuban exile vote for Clinton in the forthcoming elections. This policy could be reversed and the blockade lifted after the presidential elections have taken place. The policy of the European imperialist powers of investing with a view to carrying through the restoration of capitalism in Cuba is undoubtedly more farsighted.

Another important feature in world relations has been the tendency towards heightened frictions between the USA and some of the secondary imperialist powers. This was reflected in the opposition by French capitalism to the Israeli bombardment of the Lebanon. Reflected in this clash were the aspirations of French imperialism to try to rebuild its influence in the Lebanon and throughout the region.

The strengthened economic grip of imperialism over the former colonial countries has been reinforced as a direct consequence of the privatisations which have taken place. This is a vital aspect of developments in Asia, Africa and Latin America. The consequences have been horrific for the masses. There has been no trickle down effect . Inequality has become greater and poverty more widespread.

The policy of privatisation began earlier in Latin America than in other areas of the former colonial world. Together with other aspects of the neo-liberal agenda it has been a catastrophe for the masses. In 1980, 41 per cent of the Latin American population (136 million people) were living below the official poverty line. By 1990, the figure had risen to just under 62 per cent of the continent s population 270 million people. There has been a similar trend in relation to the Indian Sub-Continent and, most horrifically, in Africa. In Africa the trickle down effects has produced a "melt down" as whole countries are threatened with barbarism and even disintegration.

Four countries in Africa have already in effect ceased to exist Liberia, Ruanda, Somalia and Burundi. The turmoil which is taking place throughout the former colonial world is almost unprecedented. The United Nations estimated that the number of refugees was increasing in 1992 by 10,000 per day as a result of the economic situation and also as a result of wars, policies of ethnic cleansing, etc. Internationally, the UN calculated in 1987 that there were 2.5 million refugees; by 1995, the figure was 45 million. This is a measure of the depth of the crisis confronting humanity.

The character of the period is also reflected in the developments within the advanced capitalist countries. Capitalism is in a historical epoch of economic depression which is interspersed with periods of growth. Over 30 per cent of the labour force internationally is now either unemployed or underemployed. Mass unemployment is now a structural part of capitalism in the industrialised world. This does not represent a period of capitalist expansion.

These events have taken place against a background of a certain conjunctural economic growth, which has taken place in the economies of the advanced capitalist countries: limited growth in the USA, recently some growth in the Japanese economy, following four years of stagnation, and a slowdown in the European economy. In Japan growth is based on an increase in government spending and the money supply. At one point annualised GDP growth figures for Japan touched 13% this year, but such a rate of growth is unlikely to be sustained and will probably peter out .

It is necessary to be conditional about short-term economic perspectives. The recent sluggish growth which has occurred could continue for a further couple of years, although this is not certain. In Europe, there is the serious possibility that a recession could take hold of the continent. The attempts of the German ruling class to meet the criteria for the Maastricht agreement can drag the rest of the EU into recession.

Moreover, there also exists the prospect of another crash on the financial markets, where there is a marked tendency towards the overvaluing of share prices. The consequences of another crash would not he the same as 1987. Imperialism does not have the same resources it did then to intervene. Another important difference is that prior to 1987 the world economy was in an expanding phase of growth rather than the sluggish state it finds itself in during 1996. Should another financial crash occur the prospect of a slump in the world economy could be posed as a serious or even likely perspective.

The issue of structural mass unemployment is a decisive question for the workers movement. The question of job relocation is a central part of the debate on globalisation. It particularly raises the threat of the relocation of jobs from the industrialised capitalist nations to the cheap labour economies of Asia, Africa and Latin America. This process also takes place within the trading blocs established in the former colonial world where wage levels can also be quite varied.

There are some very concrete examples, like the experiences at Swiss Air and Lufthansa. They have moved all their accounting operations to India, where labour is much cheaper. Another example is that a software computer programming centre in Bangalore services over 30 multinational companies. Some countries such as Germany and Austria have also begun to relocate jobs to Eastern European countries such as the Czech Republic.

The CWI needs to develop more concrete demands and slogans to be fought for in the workers movement on this question. From the general process of the internationalisation of production the need for the international organisation of workers assumes a more concrete and practical necessity. The CWI should raise the idea of the establishment of international organisations linking workers together, workplace to workplace. This proposal is especially relevant for workers within the same multi-national company. The failure of the international trade union bureaucracy to act means it is necessary to also propose that workers by-pass officialdom. Linked to this proposal, the CWI should also explore the possibility of an international struggle to establish maximum differentials within the wage structures of the multi-nationals.

This question of job relocation poses a very real threat and it would be wrong to underestimate it. At the same time, it is also necessary to have a sense of proportion. This issue is being used by the employers as a means of intimidating workers against taking action and to force down wage levels.

However, this threat has also been exaggerated by some economists and employers who have used the ideas of the extreme globalisationists to justify it. Job relocation to the former colonial world has not been the primary reason for lay-offs in any of the industrialised countries. It is not a realistic perspective that capitalism is going to undertake a mass transfer of employment in the industrialised capitalist world to the former colonial countries.

Firstly, the immediate social consequences of such a step prevent them from doing this. Secondly, there are also economic factors which mitigate against such a drastic step. Wages and labour costs actually only account for 20 per cent of costs for the average multinational company. There are other factors, such as technique and training and securing the easiest possible access to the market itself which need also to be taken into account.

In some industries the issue of job relocation has been more of a threat than in others, partly because of the nature of production. ( e.g. textiles) These economic processes are not abstract questions. They have a direct bearing on the struggle between the classes internationally.

In a number of important European countries there has been an important revival of the movement of the proletariat. The huge events in France in December of 1995 had international repercussions. At the world congress of the CWI in 1993 we stated: In this period, it will be precisely the emergence into the arena of struggle of the working class in Germany, the US and Japan which will be a key element. In Germany that has been graphically borne out by the recent massive protests of the public sector workers. In Japan, in outline, we can see the beginnings of that process. Even in the US, there are important new features such as the possible development of a new Labour Party. We

will have to see how that development progresses. Nevertheless, it reflects the first, tentative steps being taken by the more class conscious workers in the USA.

Outside of Europe there have been massive struggles by workers and other exploited classes in society. In Sri Lanka in 1996 there was an important strike of electrical workers against privatisation. There were also the massive movements of bus workers in both India and Mexico in 1995/6 against privatisation.

As a consequence of the neo-liberal policies which have been implemented, Latin America has seen a massive revival of the mass movement. This has taken the form of strikes, general strikes, land occupations, rioting and other protests. These events have occurred from Mexico in the north to the south of Argentina. The Mexican workers and peasants mobilised in their thousands in a battle against privatisation of the oil industry. At one stage of the struggle the oil refineries were occupied by workers and peasants. There have been two general strikes in Bolivia over the past 18 months. In Paraguay where there has not been a general strike in 40 years, two one-day general strikes have been organised in the last year. In Brazil, 12 million workers participated in a 24-hour general strike in June 1996.

In a similar way, the process of integration has provoked protests in Europe. In Latin America, Paraguayan peasants have marched against MERCOSUR, as their very livelihood has been threatened by cheap imports from Brazil. The uprising in Chiapas in Mexico in 1994 was against NAFTA.

However, there are also important complications in the turmoil unleashed in this period of capitalism. The numerous national conflicts which have erupted are a measure of the impasse of capitalism. This is particularly pronounced in the Middle East. The economic collapse which taken place in Nigeria is a further measure of the devastation which the market offers the masses of Africa. Despite these social and economic disasters there have been mass movements in important countries and continents in opposition to the neo-liberal policies which have been implemented during recent years.

The increasing tendency of imperialism to economically strangle and tighten its grip over the former colonial world can provoke a powerful backlash. It will inevitably provoke the rise of powerful anti-imperialist moods and movements. The recent policy by the national bourgeoisie in the former colonial world has leant firmly in the direction of prostrating itself before imperialism. The lowering of trade barriers and the process of internationalisation of the world economy resulted for a period, in some areas of the former colonial world, in a lowering of anti-imperialist sentiment and anti-imperialist policies. This was partly because sectors of these societies hoped such measures would offer a rapid solution to the problems they faced.

This trend can also be reversed as the consequences of these policies are increasingly felt. In many of the emerging struggles the anti-imperialist content is likely to be the dominant feature. Imperialism will pay a price for the policies that have been inflicted on the masses in the former colonial world.

The outlines of such a development have already been seen in some countries. The elections in Ecuador, and also in Benin, are an indication of this. In July, Ecuador elected a new populist administration. In Benin, a former Stalinist ruler was elected President on a radical populist and anti-imperialist platform. This will be an important feature of the upheavals and struggles which are pending throughout the former colonial world.

This perspective could develop particularly in the context of a new slump or major recession in the world economy. Under the pressure of mass revolts and upheavals by workers and peasants, sections of the national bourgeoisie in some of these countries could be pushed to adopt more populist measures. They could adopt some protectionist measures and even renationalise some privatised sectors of the economy, in part to defend their own interests.

A further aspect in relation to the colonial world, is the methods of rule which are being deployed by the bourgeoisie. There has been a phase of massive illusions in democracy, particularly after 1989 90. That was reflected in important upheavals that took place in a number of continents of the former colonial world. They frequently resulted in the collapses and disintegration of the military regimes which existed, particularly in Africa. These military regimes gave way to regimes of bourgeois democracy in a series of African countries, throughout Latin America, and in some important countries in South-East Asia. However, they often have powerful features of parliamentary bonapartism.

The old state machine, in the form of the military, is still in place, and in many countries only a fig leaf of parliamentary democracy has been established. The failure to alleviate the plight of the masses, when combined with corruption and frequent waves of repression can lead to a sceptical and even hostile attitude developing towards the bourgeois institutions which are established. The programme of the CWI in these countries must also reflect the aspirations for s real democracy which can develop under such conditions. These processes have in some respects also begun to affect the industrialised countries.

The first stirrings of the masses lave been against the effects of the market and against the effects of privatisation/ neo-liberalism. During these movements the consciousness of the masses has centred on opposition to the effects of privatisation, or opposition to the idea of privatisation. In Europe it has also centred on the idea of defending services, the welfare state etc. The consciousness of these movements will reflect these issues, before moving into a phase where socialism will be accepted as a viable alternative by the mass of workers involved.

It is the absence of socialism being offered or seen as a real alternative which is the main complication at the moment on an international scale. It will re-emerge in the consciousness of workers and youth. This will come about as a result of their experiences in struggle, and through the intervention of Marxists in these events.

One of the features which has clearly emerged in the consciousness of the working class is internationalism. It partly flows from the economic processes, being reflected very practically in the struggle of the Liverpool dockers and some other struggles. It IS a by-product of NAFTA that the car workers in the USA tried to establish direct links with the car workers in Mexico and other Latin American countries.

The internationalisation of the struggle of the working class offers great scope for the work of the CWI. In this discussion on globalisation we have two tasks. Firstly, to recognise the very important changes which have taken place. he same time we must also see heir limitations and explain the real nature of the epoch through which we are passing. That is not me of new or further capitalist development but a period of economic depression.

Secondly, there is the role of the SWI in intervening in these processes. In particular, we have a central role to play in reconquering the idea of socialism as an alternative to capitalist society.

Within this process of internationalisation of the economy are also the germs of the possibilities that socialism would mean. The technical capacity to plan the economy, to organise the distribution of resources, is present in today s society. It is reflected precisely in the new technology which is utilised in the planning and marketing techniques of some of the multinationals. What is evident is the inability of capitalism to utilise and to harness the potential which exists. It certainly cannot do this from the point of view of the benefiting the mass of humanity. The CWI must demonstrate what socialism is and that it offers the only viable alternative to capitalism.

Conclusion

By David Cameron, International Secretariat of the CWI

As comrade Tony pointed out in his lead-off, and as other comrades have pointed out in the discussion, globalisation is not just an economic phenomenon. It is also an ideological and political weapon in an offensive against the international workers movement. The point of this offensive is to try to demonstrate that the market is all-powerful and that it is not possible for either national governments or the working class to do anything to resist it.

We have to reply to this offensive. But the worst thing would be to have a conservative reaction and say: Nothing has changed: globalisation is just a myth. That, of course, is not what we are saying. What we are trying to do is to clarify what has changed and what has not changed, and what are the tendencies and the countertendencies in world capitalism today, in order to arrive at an understanding of the present stage of capitalist development, the perspectives and the political consequences. This is not just a discussion about economics but also how the working class will react, how consciousness will develop and how the CWI can intervene in the situation.

In fact, when we talk about globalisation and its political consequences, it is not as simple as that: because globalisation has political causes as well as political consequences. Is it the case that globalisation represents a new and higher stage of capitalist development and that it opens up the possibility of a new period of expansion?

In the first place, as has been pointed out, there are many aspects of globalisation which are not new. In fact, the essential characteristics of imperialism as defined by Lenin in 1916 are still valid in their broad outlines. In some cases they are even more valid today than they were eighty years ago. For example, the concentration of production and capital leading to the creation of monopolies, the formation of what Lenin called international unions which we would now call multinationals or transnationals, and particularly the fusion of banking and industrial capital to form finance capital, all of which has developed incalculably further from when Lenin was writing. Of course certain things have changed, like the existence of colonial empires and the way in which the world was divided up among the imperialist powers.

However, simply to underline those points and say, Well, really, it s just the same system as in 1916, would be rather like saying: Trotsky said in 1938 that the Soviet Union would either go forward to socialism or back to capitalism. Fifty years later it went back to capitalism. So that s that! This does not explain what happened in between and what processes led to the present situation.

The point has been made that today the world economy is no more open and foreign investment direct(the export of capital) is not any more important than it was before 1914. That is true, of course, in a certain sense. However, the process was interrupted for nearly half a century, from 1914 to 1945, during which the world economy became in fact less open, where there were trade blocs, protectionism, trade wars, wars and in fact a reversal of the trends which dominated up until 1914. During this period foreign direct investment receded.

That was followed by the post-war boom, which was based on an enormous expansion of world trade rather than on an expansion of foreign direct investment. The elements of what we call today globalisation - that is the word that is used, although it is not necessarily the hest word - began to emerge with the end of the postwar boom and the beginning of the period of stagnation and depression. These were not automatic, economic processes. There were political causes. What is called the post-war consensus began to break down with the beginning of the crisis in 1973-74. All the things the working class had won or thought it had won the welfare state, full employment, rising living standards, public services began to come under attack. And because in each country, this consensus and these gains were guaranteed by the state, the neoliberal offensive took the form of an attack on the state. That is, an attack on the role of the state as an economic regulator setting limits on the power of capital, not an attack on the state as a repressive apparatus.

In practical terms this took the form of the attack on the welfare state, the offensive on wages and

employment, privatisation, which is the opening up of sectors which were previously closed off to private capital, along with the lifting of restrictions on the freedom of movement of capital, both within national boundaries and more importantly on a world scale. In fact, globalisation involves the liberation of capital from the constraints which were placed on it in the post-war period, in the period of the post-war consensus. And this process, although it accelerated with the collapse of Stalinism, began in the late 1970s.

What were the main issues raised in the discussion?

First of all, are the multinationals in the process of becoming transnationals, are they becoming what some writers call stateless, that is, free from their national bases?

That is not the case. If you look at, for example, the list of the top five hundred companies published by the Financial Times in January 1996, there are only a very tiny number which are not nationally-based. Each of those multinational companies has the name of a country beside it and that is the country where the ownership of that multinational is concentrated.

In fact, only three major exceptions come to mind: Unilever and Shell, which both date from the beginning of the century and which are both Anglo-Dutch, and Asea Brown Bovery, created in the 1980s by a fusion of Swiss and Swedish capital.

But if the multinationals have not become truly transnational from the point of view of ownership,

they have certainly become more and more transnational from the point of view of their operations. And globalisation has also seen a move away from the extremely centralised multinationals that existed in the 50s and 60s. If capital is highly centralised in its essence, it is becoming more and more decentralised from the point of view of production. What the Irish comrade said about General Motors breaking up into autonomous units is perfectly typical.

Not only that, but more and more multinationals are in the process of becoming what the French Marxist writer, Francois Chesnais has called "network firms". That is to say, firms which operate not simply by having subsidiaries in other countries but through a network of relations with other companies to which they subcontract work. Between these multinationals, there is competition, but there is also collaboration. We are seeing an increasing number of what are called "tri-polar alliances". For example, in the last few weeks, an alliance has been established in the airline industry between British Airways in Europe, United Airlines in the US and China Airlines. And in telecommunications, an alliance has been established between ATT in the US Unisource in Europe and NTT in Japan. These alliances are established in order to compete with other multinationals which have established similar alliances with other multinationals in Japan Europe and North America.

So there is an internationalisation of production and also, more and more, of services.

The second question concerns the growth of foreign direct investment, that is, export of capital. We have to ask why is there this growth, where it is going and what exactly it is?

Why, in an overall context of stagnation is it more and more necessary for firms to engage in competition on the world market and not simply within the limits of the national economy? Because in the period following the recession of 1974-75, faced with the fall in the rate of profit at home, big companies were seeking ways to get a better return on their investments and to find new markets abroad for consumer durables.

Where the investment goes is also perfectly clear: 80 per cent of foreign direct investment takes place within the triad of Europe, North America and Japan, with the difference that the export of capital from Japan to Europe and North America is much more important than the volume of investment of European and North American capital in Japan.

When we examine what foreign direct investment actually consists of we see the parasitic nature of contemporary capitalism, not only in the financial but also in the industrial sphere. Marx clearly distinguished between two processes concentration and centralisation of capital. Concentration of capital means the accumulation of capital by the creation of new means of production. This is productive investment. Centralisation means simply the fusion of existing capitals, of existing firms, which is not at all synonymous with the development of the means of production. In fact the two processes are quite opposite.

In the 1980s 75 per cent of foreign direct investment consisted not of productive investment but of fusions and acquisitions of companies in other countries. What is the difference in practice? In July, the Korean multinational, LGS, established an electronics plant in Wales, Britain. That is productive investment in the sense that a plant is going to be built, machines installed, workers hired, surplus value extracted and realised through the sale of commodities on the market. And that leads to the accumulation of capital. Non-productive investment in the sense of take-overs, acquisitions, fusions leads, in fact, to the destruction of capital. What happens when one company takes over another? It does not lead to a bigger company to more workers: it leads to less. the aim is to eliminate the competitor. Factories are closed and workers are laid off. In general only perhaps a few specialised workers, some high-technology, research and development, are kept in the new company. And it is this kind of operation that represents three-quarters of foreign direct investment.

The third question concerns regional trade blocs, which actually should be called regional trade and investment blocks. If you look at the flow of both investment and trade for the multinationals, it takes place essentially within the country and region of the multinational's origin. For example, for North American multinationals based in the US and Canada, over 70 per cent of the sales of those multinationals take place in the US and Canada and over 70 per cent of the assets of those multinationals are located in the US and Canada. And similar figures can be cited for Japanese and European multinationals: over 60 per cent in all cases. So while the multinationals are reaching out for new markets, their feet are still quite firmly planted in their own backyard.

The fourth question: can the less developed countries, the Third World countries, the countries under imperialist domination, be drawn further into the world market and can they undergo a process of economic growth? The answer to that question is such a resounding no that in fact it seems ridiculous to be talking about globalisation, to call "globalisation" a process which essentially excludes three-quarters of the world's population. Because outside the Triad, apart from a small number of newly-industrialising countries in Asia and parts of China, large areas of the world economy are excluded. And the proportion of investment which takes place within the imperialist countries and within these few Asian countries, is rising to the disadvantage of the rest of the world.

If we ask, "Is it possible for other East Asian countries to follow the road of the Asian Tigers, that is, Hong Kong, Taiwan, Singapore and South Korea?", again the answer is no. In fact, simply to look at the reasons that Tony gave for the development of the Asian Tigers and particularly of South Korea, gives you the reasons why the others won't be able to develop in a similar fashion. The elements that existed before 1980 state intervention, privileged access to the US market - do not exist any more. Under particularly favourable conditions and through consistent state intervention, South Korea was able to build up what is

extremely rare in the Third World that is, a real, internal market. South Korean products are not simply exported to the advanced capitalist world, they are also sold in South Korea. If you look at countries like Thailand, Malaysia and the Philippines, they are low-wage, exporting economies which are continually in competition with each other to receive foreign investment. And therefore a domestic market will not develop in the same way that was possible in South Korea and Taiwan.

Most of the countries of the Third World are crippled by debt repayments, by "structural adjustment programmes", and by the opening up of their economies more and more to imperialist penetration notably through the GATT agreements. Any idea that those countries are in the process of catching up with the advanced capitalist countries is contrary to the truth. In fact the gap is constantly widening between the advanced capitalist countries and most of the rest of the world.

In 1900, the ratio of the richest country in the world to the poorest country in the world was one to eight, that is, the richest country in the world was eight times richer than the poorest country in the world. In 1987 the richest country in the world was 130 times richer than the poorest country. This also illustrates that what was historically progressive under capitalism, that is, the creation of a world market and the incorporation of all the countries of the world into this market, is going into reverse and that there are more and more countries whose relation to the world market is extremely marginal.

As Tony said in his introduction, this is leading to growing development of an anti-imperialist sentiment. What Peter said about Pakistan and about the peasants in the South Punjab was very interesting. And these peasants weren't just saying in a general way: "down with imperialism" or even "down with US imperialism" or something like that. They were saying "down with the IMF, down with the World Bank". And they were absolutely right, because the IMF, the World Bank and the World Trade Organisations are increasingly the instruments through which the imperialist countries maintain their domination over the countries of the Third World.

What the Swedish comrade said in his intervention is true. The situation in the Third World is such that there is no end to the perspective of continual conflict, wars and repressive regimes. And therefore, whatever repressive legislation is adopted, whatever racist immigration laws there are, however high the wall they attempt to build, for example, around Europe, that will not stop immigrants from those countries trying to come into the advanced capitalist countries. And the CNVI has to fight for the right of those immigrants to have work and residence permits, to have civic rights and social security, not to be used as a source of cheap labour with no rights and in constant danger of deportation.

It is no accident that most of our sections in Europe are involved, or have been involved, in campaigns against racist immigration laws and particularly in defence of the right of asylum which has systematically come under attack in the whole of Europe.

The fifth question that needs to be taken up is the question of relocation. This is a phenomenon which exists but which has been enormously exaggerated from an ideological/political point of view by the ruling class and by the reformists. To say to workers in Europe that their jobs are under threat because of workers in low-wage economies in South East Asia is not only a way of seeking to divide the working class: it is also to a very large extent untrue.

As the German comrade pointed out, jobs in the advanced capitalist countries are not being transferred, they are being lost, they are being suppressed. They are being suppressed through the destruction of traditional industries and their replacement by new hi-tech industries which employ less workers, and they are being suppressed by gains in productivity. The fundamental reasons for unemployment in the advanced capitalist countries are internal to those countries and not due to any threat from, for example, South East Asia.

Only 20 per cent of the costs of production are labour costs. For example: when a product leaves a factory in South East Asia, it costs $1. When it arrives on the American market, it costs $4. At least three-quarters of the cost of that product comes not from wages but from costs of distribution and services between the point of production and the point of sale. And as the Financial Times pointed out recently, some Asian

companies are beginning to realise it is easier, rather than trying to shave five cents off the dollar paid m wages, to try to get 20-30 cents off the costs of distribution and services. And when capitalists decide to invest, to build a factory, they are not just looking at labour costs. They are looking at having a skilled workforce; they are looking at having a good communications infrastructure, financial infrastructure, and they are looking for political and economic stability in the country. They are also looking for proximity to the markets where they are going to sell their products. The director in Britain of Samsung Electronics, explaining why Samsung has decided to build a new factory in Britain, didn't say that lower wage costs were the main reason, although they are a secondary reason. He said: "The most important attraction is access to the European marketplace."

This is further demonstrated by the example that Tony cited, of Korean capital establishing a car plant in Botswana, Southern Africa It is establishing that plant there not only because of the low wages but because of easy access to the South African market. And investment is taking place, for example, in some of the Eastern European countries, particularly in Poland and in the Czech Republic, for the same reasons. There are lower wage costs compared to Western Europe but the other conditions are also present, and in particular easy access to the markets for those products.

In fact, if all the factors are taken into account - infrastructure, political stability, attitude of the working class, a skilled workforce - there are actually more reasons for establishing and investing in new plants in the lower wage areas of the European Union than outside it. And Britain, to take just that example, is attracting more and more foreign investment, not just because it is a relatively low-wage economy within Europe, but because of all the other factors, and particularly because of access to the European market.

There are of course exceptions. rake, for example the producer of sports equipment, Nike. This company employs less than 500 workers in the US, who simply design the products. The designs are then transmitted electronically to a factory in Taiwan which makes the prototypes. And the actual production takes place in South East Asia or in China: production is shifted around to find the lowest wage costs possible. That is possible with labour-intensive industries rather than with capital-intensive industries. But the increasing introduction of new technology, even within such labour-intensive industries as textiles, actually makes it less likely that production will be relocated in countries whose main advantage, from a capitalist point of view, is the availability of cheap labour.

The sixth question: it is obviously the case today that there exists a global financial market. There are large sums of money capital available for all kinds of speculative investment. But it would be wrong to imagine that there is on the one hand good industrial capital which is productive and which creates jobs and which creates value and bad speculative financial capital. It is the same capital. For example, since 1980, 18 of the biggest industrial groups in France have either established or acquired banks. And the money capital does not come from nowhere - money does not produce money. In the beginning, it comes from the production of surplus-value and lives parasitically on this surplus value. But the fact that more and more money capital is used in a speculative way, for example by investing in futures and derivatives, creates a very fragile international financial system. This is a source of concern to serious bourgeois observers.

A year ago the Economist ran an article entitled: "Where a slump could start". The place was Japan and the reason was the fragility of the Japanese financial system. Twelve months later, there has not been a slump and it did not start in Japan. But last week, the same magazine ran an article about the possibility of a Wall Street Crash and this is reinforced by the present heavy fluctuations on Wall Street. Of course we shouldn't be like the different sects who are constantly predicting the imminent collapse of capitalism and using it as a means of motivating people. Nevertheless, when serious bourgeois observers are constantly analysing the possibility of a major financial slump then the CWI should be prepared for that kind of development.

The last point to take up is the one made by the Austrian comrade, when he raised the possibilities of a new period of capitalist expansion in the former Stalinist states of Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union. Today, not even many capitalists think that is possible. At various times they have tried to convince themselves that a new period of expansion was possible through the opening of the Chinese market or through the development of the East Asian economies. as for the countries of Eastern Europe, they are now in the process of being absorbed into the world capitalist economy, but absorbed into a world capitalist economy which is in crisis and stagnation. There is not the possibility of a real period of expansion arising on that basis, but simply the kind of development we have indicated in relation to Eastern Europe and the European Union.

It is very difficult to imagine any kind of stable integration of Russia into the world economy. In a general sense, for capitalist expansion, for the accumulation of capital to take place, more than capital and workers are needed - so are markets. Goods need to be produced cheaply and they have to be sold afterwards. This is the Achilles heel of the idea that China offers a way forward for world capitalism.

Is it possible for one country to resist the pressures of the world market and the political pressures of imperialism and the imperialist institutions? In a general sense the answer is no. The tendency is for countries and governments to knuckle under to the pressure of the world market and imperialism. But there are exceptions. For example, South Korea is not yet a member of the OECD, although economically it is much more powerful than several of the existing members. And it is not yet a member because it is refusing, up to now, to give in to the dictates of the OECD in terms of opening up and liberalising the Korean market and particularly the agricultural sector. It is doing that to defend Korean firms, but also quite explicitly for fear of the social and political consequences of allowing that kind of liberalisation.

China is now starting to say: "We want foreign investment, but we don't want any old foreign investment. We don't just want foreign investment in labour-intensive industries, we want foreign investment in hi-tech industries. And we don't just want investment in the coastal zones, we want investment in the interior as well because we

are afraid of the social consequences of this dual economy that is developing."

There is a conflict between the Indonesian government on the one hand and General Motors and Toyota on the other. The Indonesian government is talking about subsidising a "national car" which will be built in Indonesia with the participation of Korean capital. This is completely counter to free market liberal policies. It is also obvious that there are strong protectionist tendencies in Russia.

The overwhelming tendency is for all those resistances to the neo-liberal order to be broken down due to the pressure of the world market and the political pressure of imperialism. But those counter-tendencies exist, just as the germs of protectionism which exist in the regional trade blocs. And under conditions of an economic downturn, a return to protectionism, not exactly national autarchy, but at least regional self-sufficiency, is quite possible. And although renationalisation in the Third World is not exactly excluded, what is much more possible is what the Austria comrade talked about, which is state intervention to support industries by means of subsidies and government contracts.

Finally, it needs to be underlined that although we can identify and analyse the process of globalisation, we shouldn't imagine that it will go on forever and that it is irreversible. The history of the 20th Century goes against such a view. In the same way, although there is no stable prospect of Keynesian policies or left reformism, that does not mean there will be no attempts at reformist strategies in the medium term. In a situation of crisis and with mass pressure from below there will be a development of reformism. In the meantime, as the French comrade said, it would be a big mistake to think that because there is a process of bourgeoisification of the workers' parties, and because of the sharp shift to the right of the trade union leaders, reformism is going to disappear. On the contrary, reformism is still there and is still the major obstacle to a working-class fightback against the capitalist offensive.

[To go CWI HomePage]
[To go CWI (Australia)]
[To send comment to Militant (Australia)]