H ca.geocities.com /econ_0909meet/north-autobio.html ca.geocities.com/econ_0909meet/north-autobio.html elayed x zJ z J OK text/html /? J b.H Sun, 31 Aug 2008 07:32:52 GMT w Mozilla/4.5 (compatible; HTTrack 3.0x; Windows 98) en, * zJ J
I
was born in Cambridge, Massachusetts - not because my family had any connection
with higher education, but because my father was a manager at the Metropolitan
Life Insurance Company in a nearby town and Cambridge was the nearest hospital
- in 1920. In the ensuing years we moved a number of times as a result of my
father's business. First Connecticut and then, when he became head of the Metropolitan's
Canadian office, Ottawa. Because my mother believed in education broadly construed,
we also lived in Europe and I went to school at the Lycée Jacquard in
Lausanne, Switzerland, in 1929-30. My brother and sister are both older than
I am and were born before my father went off to World War I.
I went to elementary school
in Ottawa, and then to a private secondary school.
When we moved back to the United States in 1933, I went to private schools in
New York City and on Long Island, and then completed my high school education
at the Choate School in Wallingford, Connecticut. While I was there I became
deeply interested in photography, and indeed the most noteworthy event in my
early life was winning first, third, fourth and seventh prizes in an international
competition for college and high school students.
Our family life was certainly not intellectual. My father had not even completed
high school when he started as an office boy working for the Metropolitan Life
Insurance Company, and I am not sure that my mother completed high school. Nevertheless,
she was an exciting person, intelligent, intellectually curious, and she played
an important part in my intellectual development. My aunt and uncle were, and
in the case of my aunt (Adelaide North) still is, a powerful influence. They
introduced me to classical music
and my aunt continues to be, to this day, a
very special person in my life.
When it came time to go to college, I had been accepted for Harvard when my
father was offered the position of head of the Metropolitan Life Insurance Company
office on the west coast, and we moved to San Francisco. Because I did not want
to be that far from home, I decided to go instead to the University of California
at Berkeley. While I was there my life was completely changed by becoming a
convinced Marxist and engaging in a variety of student liberal activities. I
was opposed to World War II, and indeed on June 22, 1941 when Hitler invaded
the Soviet Union I suddenly found myself the lone supporter of peace since everybody
else had, because of their communist beliefs, shifted over to become supporters
of the war. My record at the University of California as an undergraduate was
mediocre to say the best. I had only slightly better than a "C" average, although
I did have a triple major in political science, philosophy, and economics. I
had hoped to go to law school, but the war started, and because of the strong
feeling that I did not want to kill anybody, I joined the Merchant Marine when
I graduated from Berkeley. We had been to sea only a short time when the Captain
called me up on the bridge and asked me if I could learn to navigate since most
of the officers had had only rudimentary education, and we needed to get from
San Francisco to Australia. I became navigator and enjoyed it very much. We
made repeated trips from San Francisco to Australia, and then to the front lines
in New Guinea and the Solomon Islands.
What the war did was give me the opportunity of three years of continuous reading,
and it was in the course of reading that I became convinced that I should become
an economist. Then the last year of the war I taught celo-navigation at the
Maritime Service Officers' School in Alameda, California; I took up photography
again and had a difficult decision as to whether to become a photographer or
go into economics. In the summer of 1941 I had worked with Dorothea Lange, head
of the photographic division of the Farm Security Administration, travelling
with and photographing migrants through the central valley of California. Now
Dorothea tried to persuade me to become a photographer. Her husband, Paul Taylor,
who was in the economics department at the University of California, tried to
persuade me to become an economist. He won.
I went back to graduate school with the clear intention that what I wanted to
do with my life was to improve societies, and the way to do that was to find
out what made economies work the way they did or fail to work. I believed that
once we had an understanding of what determined the performance of economies
through time, we could then improve their performance. I have never lost sight
of that objective.
I cannot say that I learned much formal economics as a graduate student in Berkeley.
My most influential professors were Robert Brady; Leo Rogin, a Marxist and a
very influential teacher of history of economic thought; and M. M. Knight (Frank
Knight's brother) who certainly was agnostic, to say the least, about theory,
but who had a wonderful knowledge of the facts and background in economic history.
He became my mentor and my thesis advisor at Berkeley. But while I learned by
rote most of the theory I was supposed to know, I did not acquire a real understanding
of theory. It was not until I got my first job, at the University of Washington
in Seattle, and began playing chess with Don Gordon, a brilliant young theorist,
that I learned economic theory. In the three years of playing chess every day
from noon to two, I may have beaten Don at chess, but he taught me economics;
more important he taught me how to reason like an economist, and that skill
is still perhaps the most important set of tools that I have acquired.
I had written my dissertation on the history of life insurance in the United
States and had had a Social Science Research Council Fellowship to go to the
east coast and do the spade work. That turned out to be a very productive year.
I not only sat in on Robert Merton's seminars in sociology at Columbia, but
also became deeply involved in the Entrepreneurial school of Arthur Cole at
Harvard. The result was that Joseph Schumpeter had a strong influence upon me.
My early work and publications centered around expanding on the analysis of
life insurance in my dissertation and its relationship to investment banking.
I next turned to developing an analytical framework to look at regional economic
growth and this led to my first article in the Journal of Political Economy,
entitled "Location Theory and Regional Economic Growth". That work eventually
led me to developing a staple theory of economic growth.
I was very fortunate that at a meeting of the Economic Douglass - North C. Logan Douglass GetZ North C. Hyundai - Accent Renault History Association I
come to know Solomon Fabricant, who was then director of research at the National
Bureau of Economic Research; and in 1956-57 I was invited to spend the year
at the Bureau as a research associate. That was an enormously important year
in my life. I not only became acquainted with most of the leading economists
who passed through the bureau, but spent one day a week in Baltimore with Simon
Kuznets and did the empirical work that led to my early major quantitative study
of the balance of payments of the United States from 1790 to 1860.
I married for the first time in 1944. During my graduate training my wife taught
school, providing our major source of support. We had three sons, Douglass,
Christopher, and Malcolm, born between 1951 and 1957. After the boys were in
school my wife became a successful politician in the Washington State legislature.
Between my year at the National Bureau and 1966-67, when I went off to Geneva
as a Ford Faculty Fellow, I did my major work in American economic history,
which led to my first book, The Economic Growth of the United States from
1790 to 1860. It was a straightforward analysis of how markets work in the
context of an export staple model of growth.
By this time (1960) there was a substantial stirring to try to change and transform
economic history. The year that I was at NBER,
the Bureau and C. North - zoophilia man Douglass the Economic Douglass lingerie party North - C. History
Douglass stories - C. sex free North rape Association had free rape pics C. Douglass - North the first joint quantitative program zoophilia Douglass man - C. North on the growth of the American
economy, a conference that was held at Williamstown, Massachusetts, in the late
spring of 1957. This meeting was really the beginning of the new economic history,
but the program coalesced when Jon Hughes and Lance Davis, two former students
of mine who had become faculty members at Purdue, called the first conference
of economic historians interested in trying to develop and apply economic theory
and quantitative methods to history. The first meeting was held in February
of 1960. This program was highly successful and the reception that it received
amongst economists was certainly enthusiastic. Economics departments very quickly
became interested in having new economic historians, or, as we came to call
ourselves, cliometricians (Clio being the muse of history). Therefore, as I
developed a graduate program jointly with my colleague Morris David Morris at
the University of Washington we attracted some of the best students to do work
in economic history, and during the 1960s and early 70s the job market was very
responsive and our students were easily placed throughout the country.
In 1966-67 I decided that I should switch from American to European economic
history, and therefore, when I received the above-mentioned grant to live in
Geneva for a year, I decided to re-tool. Re-tooling turned out to change my
life radically, since I quickly became convinced that the tools of neo-classical
economic theory were not up to the task of explaining the kind of fundamental
societal change that had characterized European economies from medieval times
onward. We needed new tools, but they simply did not exist. It was in the long
search for a framework that would provide new tools of analysis that my interest
and concern with the new institutional economics evolved. The result was two
initial books, one with Lance Davis, Institutional Change and American Economic
Growth, and the other with Robert Thomas, The Rise of the Western World:
A New Economic History.
Both books were early tentative attempts to develop some tools of institutional
analysis and apply them to economic history. Both were still predicated on neo-classical
economic theory, and there were too many loose ends that did not make sense:
such as the notion that institutions were efficient (however defined). Perhaps
more serious, it was not possible to explain long-run poor economic performance
in a neo-classical framework. So I began to explore what was wrong. Individual
beliefs were obviously important to the choices people make, and only the extreme
myopia of economists prevented them from understanding that ideas, ideologies,
and prejudices mattered. Once you recognize that, you are forced to examine
the rationality postulate critically.
The long road towards developing a new analytical framework involved taking
all of these considerations seriously: to develop a view of institutions that
would account for why institutions produced results that in the long run did
not manage to produce economic growth; develop a model of political economy
in order to be able to handle and explain the underlying source of institutions.
Finally, one had to come to grips with why people had the ideologies and ideas
that determined the choices they made.
In Structure and Change in Economic History (1981) I abandoned the notion
that institutions were efficient and attempted to explain why "inefficient"
rules would tend to exist and be perpetuated. This was tied to a very simple
and still neo-classical theory of the state which could explain why the state
could produce rules that did not encourage economic growth. I was still dissatisfied
with our understanding of the political process, and indeed searched for colleagues
who were interested in developing political-economic models. This led me to
leave the University of Washington in 1983 after being there for 33 years, and
to move to Washington University in St. Louis, where there was an exciting group
of young political scientists and economists who were attempting to develop
new models of political economy. This proved to be a felicitous move. I created
the Center in Political Economy, which continues to be a creative research center.
The development of a political-economic framework to explore long-run institutional
change occupied me during all of the 1980s and led to the publication of Institutions,
Institutional Change and Economic Performance in 1990. In that book I began
to puzzle seriously about the rationality postulate. It is clear that we had
to have an explanation for why people make
the choices they do; why ideologies
such as communism or Muslim fundamentalism can shape the choices people make
and direct the way economies evolve through long periods of time. One simply
cannot get at ideologies without digging deeply into cognitive science in attempting
to understand the way in which the mind acquires learning and makes choices.
Since 1990, my research has been directed toward dealing with this issue. I
still have a long way to go, but I believe that an understanding of how people
make choices; under what conditions the rationality postulate is a useful tool;
and how individuals make choices under conditions of uncertainty and ambiguity
are fundamental questions that we must address in order to make further progress
in the social sciences.
In 1972 I married again, to Elisabeth Case; she continues to be wife, companion,
critic and editor: a partner in the projects and programs that we undertake.
I would be remiss if I left the impression that my life has been totally preoccupied
with scholarly research. True, it has been the fundamental focus of my life,
but it has been intermingled with a variety of activities that have complemented
that central preoccupation and enriched my life. I continue to be a photographer;
I have enjoyed fishing and hunting with a close friend; and have owned two ranches,
first in northern California and then in the state of Washington. I learned
to fly an airplane, and had my own airplane during the 1960s. I have always
taken seriously good food and wine. In addition, music has continued to be an
important part of my life.
My wife and I now live in the summers in northern Michigan in an environment
which is wonderfully conducive to research, and where most of my work in the
last 15 years has been done. I work on
research all morning. In the afternoons
I hike with my dog, play tennis or go swimming. In the evening, as we are only
16 miles from the National Music Camp at Interlochen, we may listen to music
two or three nights a week. It is a wonderful place for that mixture of research
and leisure which has made my life such a rich experience.
From Les Prix Nobel. The Nobel Prizes 1993, Editor Tore Frängsmyr, [Nobel Foundation], Stockholm, 1994
This autobiography/biography was written at the time of the award and later published in the book series Les Prix Nobel/Nobel Lectures. The information is sometimes updated with an addendum submitted by the Laureate. To cite this document, always state the source as shown above.