Determinants of Public Debt Growth within Pakistan

"I place economy among the first and most important virtues, and public debt as the greatest of dangers. To preserve our independence, we must not let our rulers load us with perpetual debt."
           
                                                                                                -Thomas Jefferson-

 Public debt is the sum of governmental financial obligations; which are the result of a state’s borrowing from its population, from foreign governments or from international institutions. Public debts tend to be large-scale credit operations and are contracted on a national scale by central governments and on a lesser scale by provincial, regional, district and municipal administrative authorities.

             National public debts are contracted mainly by incurring interest paying loans, in the form of bonds, bills or notes. Governments have taken loans to meet national budget or expenditures that remain uncovered by revenues; or to seek to improve economic conditions by counteracting unemployment or depressions, or both with deficit budgets. Not all financial authorities agree that nations should carry a high level of public debt, as it can be inflationary. Rather than the level of debt, however, the most important consideration is the capacity of a nation to service its debt.

             Some long term maturing debt is repaid by short-term borrowing that does not add significantly to the total debt level. The redeeming of public debt includes the repayment of principal on maturity, amortization through periodic payment of part of principal, and the buying up of government securities on the open market. Most government loans fall due at fixed dates, but some perpetual loans have no definite expiration dates, and governments floating them have the privilege of redeeming them when desirable.

             Most government loans are not secured by physical assets, however they are regarded in law as contracts carrying an obligation on the part of the debtor to repay, nevertheless governments when hard pressed during economic crises or as a result of political upheavals, have sometimes refused to repay their public debts.

 In a broader macroeconomic context for public policy, governments should seek to ensure that both the level and rate of growth in their public debt is fundamentally sustainable, and can be serviced under a wide range of circumstances while meeting cost and risk objectives. Sovereign debt managers share fiscal and monetary policy advisors' concerns that public sector indebtedness remains on a sustainable path and that a credible strategy is in place to reduce excessive levels of debt. Debt managers should ensure that the fiscal authorities are aware of the impact of government financing requirements and debt levels on borrowing costs.[1] Examples of indicators that address the issue of debt sustainability include the public sector debt service ratio, and ratios of public debt to GDP and to tax revenue.

 Poorly structured debt in terms of maturity, currency, or interest rate composition and large and unfunded contingent liabilities have been important factors in inducing or propagating economic crises in many countries throughout history. For example, irrespective of the exchange rate regime, or whether domestic or foreign currency debt is involved, crises have often arisen because of an excessive focus by governments on possible cost savings associated with large volumes of short-term or floating rate debt. This has left government budgets seriously exposed to changing financial market conditions, including changes in the country's creditworthiness, when this debt has to be rolled over. Foreign currency debt also poses particular risks, and excessive reliance on foreign currency debt can lead to exchange rate and/or monetary pressures if investors become reluctant to refinance the government's foreign-currency debt. By reducing the risk that the government's own portfolio management will become a source of instability for the private sector, prudent government debt management, along with sound policies for managing contingent liabilities, can make countries less susceptible to contagion and financial risk.

A government's debt portfolio is usually the largest financial portfolio in the country. It often contains complex and risky financial structures, and can generate substantial risk to the government's balance sheet and to the country's financial stability. As noted by the Financial Stability Forum's Working Group on Capital Flows (USA), "recent experience has highlighted the need for governments to limit the build-up of liquidity exposures and other risks that make their economies especially vulnerable to external shocks."[2] Therefore, sound risk management by the public sector is also essential for risk management by other sectors of the economy "because individual entities within the private sector typically are faced with enormous problems when inadequate sovereign risk management generates vulnerability to a liquidity crisis." Sound debt structures help governments reduce their exposure to interest rate, currency and other risks. Many governments seek to support these structures by establishing, where feasible, portfolio benchmarks related to the desired currency composition, duration, and maturity structure of the debt to guide the future composition of the portfolio.

 Several debt market crises have highlighted the importance of sound debt management practices and the need for an efficient and sound capital market. Although government debt management policies may not have been the sole or even the main cause of these crises, the maturity structure, and interest rate and currency composition of the government's debt portfolio, together with substantial obligations in respect of contingent liabilities have often contributed to the severity of the crisis. Even in situations where there are sound macroeconomic policy settings, risky debt management practices increase the vulnerability of the economy to economic and financial shocks. Sometimes these risks can be readily addressed by relatively straightforward measures, such as by lengthening the maturities of borrowings and paying the associated higher debt servicing costs (assuming an upward sloping yield curve), by adjusting the amount, maturity, and composition of foreign exchange reserves, and by reviewing criteria and governance arrangements in respect of contingent liabilities.

 Risky debt structures are often the consequence of inappropriate economic policies--fiscal, monetary and exchange rate--but the feedback effects undoubtedly go in both directions. However, there are limits to what sound debt management policies can deliver. Sound debt management policies are no solution or substitute for sound fiscal and monetary management. If macroeconomic policy settings are poor, sound sovereign debt management may not by itself prevent any crisis. Sound debt management policies reduce susceptibility to drawbacks and financial risk by playing a pivotal role for broader financial market development and financial deepening. Experience supports the argument, for example, that developed domestic debt markets can substitute for bank financing (and vice versa) when this source dries up, helping economies to weather financial shocks.[3]

 Literature Review:

            Over the years, ever piling domestic debt was less of a concern as compared to the external context of debt. However, during the last decade this topic has occupied primal importance not just in the local but also in the international arena.

            Flowers 1989, was certainly the first one to discuss the constitutional politics of public debt. Even before this Buchanan and Roback 1987 explored the implications of public debt in a world populated simultaneously by some individuals willing to leave positive and others wishing to leave negative bequests. However, this was a mere theoretical review with application not possible across countries. A deregulated picture was given by Lott 1990, where the discussion was quite rich as regards the predation by public enterprises. Another scenario integrating public debt, deficits, and inflation is observable in Buiter and Patel 1991. This analysis was fundamentally a case study of India, but provided important insight for the operational predicaments being faced by the emerging third world countries.

            Burney 1988 for the first time came up with certainly the most comprehensive study regarding the debt problem in Pakistan and its debt servicing capacity. After this, there were several writings, but most of them were only the warning signals for the rising external commitments. Precisely this was also the time when government resorted to domestic borrowing, whose repayment was latter to become an enigmatic dilemma. Tahir 1998 discussed the present plus the predicted positions of internal and external debt. (This paper will be discussed in quite a detail under latter headings). Another forecast of future trends was made available in Ahmed 1998. Over here, the author has projected that in 1997-98 the internal debt (41.51% of GDP) was greater than External debt (31.11% of GDP). But as the capacity of internal resources dry out the position of 2019-20 will be that the External debt (69.33% of GDP) will be considerably higher than internal debt which is estimated to be about 33.22% of GDP.

             Another recent effort can be observed in Hassan 1999; where the changing nature of Pakistan’s debt problem has been elucidated (in a manner, so as to show the evolution of the debt problem).

 Historical perspective and the present burden of Public Debt:

             Pakistan during the last half century started from the scratch primarily as an agrarian economy to be transformed into a semi-industrialized state. Golden 60s was a period of amazing economic growth, due to factors like massive foreign aid, imports substititution (for manufacturing sector), green revolution, increased rewards in the private sector etc. The era of 70s brought about great economic and political distress for the citizens in the form of; breakup of Pakistan, initiation of a mismanaged nationalization policy, oil shock, trade balance deficit (due to deterioration of terms of trade) etc. Yet, the decade was somehow sustained and the gap reduced; attributable to a mega rise in workers remittances from Gulf.

            Early 80s also witnessed the remittance flow that provided a breathing space to an economy about to witness fundamental changes. Trade liberalization was the new direction complimented by the adoption of flexible exchange rate regime.[4]  This was the starting point in the downfall of one of the fastest growing developing nations. In mid 80s the deficit (fiscal) increased to 8% of GDP, as the rising government expenditures levied its toll. This in turn led to a soaring of external and domestic borrowing. Ultimately this borrowing was to cripple the nation’s progress in future. Despite manufacturing sector’s expansion and booming domestic market, late 80s witnessed a deepening of the balance of payment crises. On one side the economy was being injected with increased benefits from illegal trade income (partly due to Afghanistan crises), while on the other end large debt servicing, saturating trend in investment and savings plus the decreasing inflows started to set in.[5] By 1990 civil war in Karachi hindered the manufacturing capacity of the largest industrial city of Pakistan in regretting manner.

As compared to the foreign aid, acquiring of public debt was a relatively new phenomenon (see table I). Infact it was during Zia regime, when the public debt grew six folds (at a real average annual rate of 10%). At this time, the main source of growth in real debt was the expanding of primary deficit. In turn these persistent fiscal deficits have resulted in exponential growth of debt servicing. By 1998-99, the proportion of interest payments to revenues rose to well over 40%. 

 

Text Box: 					Table 1
Pakistan’s Public Debt 			     (billions)

Year			Domestic Debt		External Debt		Total Debt

1979–80	56.8     (24.3)			70.7     (30.2)		137.5   (54.5)
1880-81		60.1     (21.6)			73.9     (26.7)		134.0   (48.3)
1984-85		143.9   (30.5)			140.2   (29.7)		284.1   (60.2)
1985-86		200.1   (39.0)			186.8   (36.3)		387.6   (75.3)
1986-87		247.3   (43.2)			208.6   (36.4)		455.9   (79.6)
1987-88		288.6   (42.7)			232.4   (34.4)		521.0   (77.1)
1988-89		331.1   (43.0)			299.4   (38.9)		630.5   (81.9)
1989-90		378.3   (44.4)			328.9   (38.4)		707.2   (82.6)
1990-91		445.1   (43.6)			436.3   (38.4)		821.1   (80.5)
1991-92		521.8   (43.1)			436.3   (36.0)		958.1   (79.1)
1992-93		602.4   (44.9)			517.2   (38.6)		1119.6 (83.4)
1993-94		702.0   (44.6)			749.4   (47.6)		1451.4 (92.2)
1994-95		798.6   (42.4)			785.1   (41.7)		1731.7 (84.1)
1995-96		908.9   (42.4)			951.0   (44.4)		1859.9 (86.8)
1996-97		1041.9 (43.3)			1127.3 (46.9)		2169.2 (90.2)
1997-98		1151.4 (41.7)			1366.9 (49.5)		2518.3 (91.2)
1998-99		1389.3 (47.7)			1581.9 (54.3)		2971.2 (102.0)
					        Note: Figures in brackets are ratios to GDP in nominal terms

As the 90s closed their account, the world saw a failed case of democracy in the shape of Pakistan’s political and economic trauma. During the whole of 90s decade until now governments could do nothing to improve the expenditure side let alone the incomes side that was to derive impetus with the right mix of development and productive expenditure. Today the country faces three major cost yielding burdens:

                                 i.            Debt Servicing,

                               ii.            Military expenditure,

                              iii.            Establishment costs.

Deepening of debt problem has hollowed the economic stabilization mechanism. As far as the external debt is concerned, Pakistan has help of multilateral agencies in the form of rescheduling and rollovers. On the contrary, domestic debt has started to pose multidimensional problems. While the ratio of public debt to GDP increase to over 100% in 1998-99, the ratio of debt to revenues increase to 600%, along with the proportion of interest payments to revenues climbing well over 40%.[6]

At present, the giving of a judgment of Pakistan’s existent economic position becomes even difficult where we have weak executioners. Although the present government has made apparent efforts towards objectives like the implementation of transparent financial reforms, documentation of economy (through nation wide tax survey, with a view to broaden he general sales tax net), anti-smuggling trade measures, cut in establishment costs, curtailing the military expenditure etc. but the tangible rewards of the aforementioned efforts have yet to be sighted.

 

Text Box: 					Table 2
		      Key Economic Variables influencing Public Debt
		           		             1977-88	         1988-96		        1996-99

Nominal debt Growth²		    17.8			17.2			 15.8
Real Debt Growth²		      	     9.6			6.1			 6.0
Real GDP Growth²		      	     6.7			5.7			 2.8
Inflation²			      	     7.5			10.5			 9.1
Real Govt. Revenue Growth²	      	     9.0			4.5			 0.0
Fiscal Deficit as % of GDP	      	     7.2			7.5			 6.9
Primary Deficit as % of GDP	      	     4.2			2.0			-0.2
Primary Deficit as % of Debt	      	     7.3			2.6			-0.2
Real Interest Rate on Debt²	      	     2.1			3.5			 6.2
								(²percent per annum)

We can observe from table 2, that the general economic factors that went against the scenario also aggravated the debt problem. The real revenues show a saturated position. Three reasons can be classified for this trend. First major reductions in income tax, sales tax and the customs duty rates lowered the tax base.

Secondly, the persisting governance problem has weakened the compact between the state and citizens, thus leading to a growing resistance towards paying taxes.

Text Box: 					Table 3
			    Indicators of Public Debt Burden
             Public debt as    Public debt as      Interest Payments   Interest payments  Total Debt   Total Debt
            % of GDP	         %of  Revenues    as % of GDP          as % of revenues     payments    payments as
									as % of      % of  
Year									GDP           Revenues
1979-80	     54.5		357		2.2		13.2		 4.6		27.8
1984-85	     60.2		367		3.6		21.3		 4.5		32.3
1987-88	     77.1		445		3.8		28.4		 5.8		39.9
1989-90	     82.6		431		5.4		28.5		 7.6		41.6
1992-93	     83.4		467		6.2		32.9		 8.4		45.1
1995-96	     86.8		505		6.2		36.0		 9.0		54.4
1996-97	     90.2		564		6.6		41.9		10.7		67.3
1997-98	     91.2		557		7.3		41.8		10.4		61.5
1998-99	     102.0		624		7.3		42.6		-		-
								     Source: State Bank Reports


            Thirdly, the increase in revenues in the 1980’s relying heavily as it did on foreign trade taxes was not sustainable. Over here, we would also like to discuss the role of interest rates (see table 4). Until 1980’s most of government borrowing was acquired at a level below market rates. Then after ’89 as a part of World Bank supported financial sector reforms, the move towards a market based interest rates determination lost its target due to the accelerated inflation. Meanwhile governments have also resorted to non-bank sources for borrowing. The introduction of various savings schemes has been an episode in the non-bank sources. (Under these schemes as well, the interest and inflation rates levied their toll).

 

Text Box: Table 4
			Average Interest Rate on Domestic Debt
Year 			Nominal Average			 Real Interest Rate
Interest Rate (%)

1979-80			5.0					-6.0
1981-82			6.4					-3.0
1983-84			7.5					-2.2
1984-85			7.5					 3.0
1985-86			7.1					 3.8
1986-87			7.0					 2.5
1987-88			8.4					-1.2
1990-91			8.8					-4.3
1992-93			11.2					-2.5
1993-94			12.0					-0.9
1994-95			10.5					-3.7
1995-96			12.3					 4.3
1996-97			13.0					-0.3
1997-98			15.1					 7.3
1998-99			13.7					 7.7

A worth noticing phenomenon in Table 3 in the extraordinary increase in Public Debt to revenue percentage. If we simply relate this ratio to the rise in deficits (table 2), then one realizes that this sharp upward trend has certainly forced the economic forecasters to sign in a very bleak picture for future.

 

 

 

Methodology:

           

            National or public debt comprises of two brackets:        I- Internal or Domestic Debt

                                                                                               II- External debt

 

Both these categories demand isolated analysis not in the partial sense but in the context of empirical interdependence. For this purpose, we would first take Model 1 for the evaluation of: “Determinants of growth in External debt”.

          

For simplicity, we will deduce the growth determinants as exhibited by the ‘ratio of External debt to GDP’. This working has been adopted from the works of Swender Van Wijenbergen 1989.

Then in Model 2, we would extend Swender’s model for deducing the determinants of growth in domestic debt of Pakistan. We must also bear in mind that several of these determinants depict a correlated behavior towards each other. This intensity of correlation needs critical investigation.

            As for now we take up two important issues:

                        i) The debt trap; as seen in the chart, the accumulation of debt is not merely an isolated process resulting from a short fall of revenues in comparison with the expenditures, but it is a very integrated process which is complemented by two other factors namely, the debt servicing and the borrowings.

 ii) The treatment of budget deficits (which are of course the main cause of debt accumulation) also needs to be considered from the view point of National accounts. The basic accounting identity for deficits is as follows:

Budget deficit = Primary Budget Deficit + Interest Payments on outstanding Public Debt

           For the financing of budget deficits, consider the following equation:

 

Budget Deficit = Money Printing + Foreign Reserve Use + Foreign Borrowing + Domestic Borrowing   

 

For the acquiring of debt governments at different levels, make use of several instruments. The major Public debt instruments (in Pakistan) and their characterstics are available in Appendix II.

 

            Model 1:

            We focus in this model on the changes in the External Debt to GDP ratio, and the factor responsible for these changes.

Consider the following expression by Swender van Wijenbergen 1989:

 

Where ‘De’ is the external debt, ‘E’ the exchange rate, NICAD = non-interest current account balance, ‘y’ = GDP, ‘r’ is the real interest rate on external debt, and ‘g’ is the real GDP growth. So that the equation implies:

 

Absolute change in external debt = (Noninterest current account deficit) + (interest payments on external debt) + absolute magnitude of capital loss on external debt (due to exchange rate)

Thus the equation reveals that the change in the external debt to GDP ratio is attributable to three factors as follows:

i)                                            The non-interest current account balance. The larger the deficit in the current account of the balance of payments, excluding interest payments, the greater the increase in the external debt due to larger borrowings;

ii)                                           The extent to which the real interest rate, r, on the foreign debt exceeds the growth rate, of the economy;

iii)                                         The rate of capital loss on external debt due to real exchange rate depreciation, dE/E[7]

 

Results of the application of the methodology in equation (1) have been exhibited in the Appendix I. Over here, we outline the main interpretations of our empirical work in the perspective of policy implications as follows:

      

The pattern of change in the external debt differs fundamentally between the decade of the 80s and the 90s. In the former period, the cumulative increase in the ratio was about 13.5 percentage points (appendix 1), whereas in the first half of the decade of the 90s there was an overall fall of 5.7 percentage points. The second half of the 90s again saw a dramatic increase in the foreign debt burden more so due to the servicing costs. What needs to be clearly seen over here is; why has there been greater success in curtailing the external debt burden in the first half of the 90s despite the sharp fall in the real growth rate of the economy? The main reason for this is the difference in the rate of real exchange rate depreciation and not in the size of the current account deficits (appendix1). During the 80s Pakistan followed an aggressive exchange rate policy which actually led to increasing under valuation of the rupee in terms of purchasing power parity, and the real exchange rate fell on average each year by as much as 2.8 percent. This implied major capital losses and rapid increases in the rupee value of external debt. On the contrary, during the first half of 90s the rupee has moved, more or less, in line with changes in purchasing power parity with only marginal changes in the real effective exchange rate (appendix 1). One again observes a jump in the external debt/GDP ratio due to the continued devaluation starting from November 1995.[8]

The nature of our analysis completely changes in the latter half of 90s until now. We encounter a change in the determinants of foreign debt burden in a manner that diverts our attention from the deficits and exchange rate effects and drives the focus upon the mega interest payments taking the shape of debt servicing. As it is evident from the results, that interest payment on external debt has the highest coefficient value with the most significant t-statistic result.[9] Similarly after 1995, we also observe an increasing trend in the current account deficit (non interest), which also adversely affected the extent by which Pakistan was dependent on foreign sources of borrowing. Even in the early 80s, it can be recognized that the current account deficits could have increased the magnitude of effect on the external debt to GDP ratio, but this feared increase did not take place due to the fact that throughout the period the real interest rate on external debt was substantially below the real growth rate of economy (Table 2). In that era, the access of Pakistan to concessionary financing from multilateral and bilateral agencies has been a major factor responsible for restricting the level of external debt to GDP ratio.

 

 Model 2

             Total debt ‘D’ is composed of Dd i.e. the domestic debt and the ‘DeE’ i.e. the external debt (multiplied by the exchange rate change ‘E’) as shown in equation 1.

                         D = Dd + DeE                                                                          1

 In equation 2 we open up the 1st equation to see the combined determinants of both types of debt.

                                  2

Where, PBD is the Primary Budget Deficit, while the rest of the notations are same as above.

            Thus from equation 2 we take out those factors that have contributed towards the domestic debt. In addition to those factors we also make the real inflation rate responsible as in the 3rd equation below:                      

Dd = f (PBD + Interest payments + inflation rate)                         3

Results of the analysis based on equation 3 are as follows:

                  

    Primary budget deficit generally, is identified as a determinant of overall national or public debt. We over here regard primary budget deficit as the main factor that has contributed towards an increase in the domestic debt earlier on. As for the latter part, the main culprit will be the interest burden on the internal debt that made the matters worse off. There was a sharp increase in the public debt to GDP ratio by almost 28 percent between 1980-81 and 1994-95, with most of the increase in domestic debt. As pointed out earlier the major factor contributing to the rise in the debt was the cumulative effect of successive large primary budget deficits. This trend slowed down as the actual size of deficit in relation to the GDP declined in the first half of the 90s. But this is precisely the time when we encounter a noticeable jump in interest payments on almost all types of domestic debt (in 1991-92). This rise can be attributed to the financial sector liberalization, leading to an institution of market based interest rate structure in government debt instruments like treasury bills.

            However, the actual rate of domestic debt growth, which in 80s was 22 percent, declined to 16 percent in the first half of 90s. However, this was not to remain the same in the latter years of 90s, when until 1998 the domestic debt soared to a little less than two fold as compared to the level of 1994.

 

Text Box: 				Internal outstanding Debt
Rs.billion
                       	         1995-96	          1996-97	         1997-98	         1998-99	          1999-00
Total 
domestic debt		920.3		1056.1		1199.7		1452.7		1622.4

·	Permanent	291.4		289.3		286.6		317.2		 306.3
·	Floating	361.3		433.8		473.8		561.6		 646.6
·	Unfunded	267.6		332.9		439.2		573.9		 669.5

             The rapid rise in interest payments on domestic debt has resulted in a structural change in the pattern of interest payment in the country. In 1980-81, over 40 percent of the interest paid, was on external debt. This proportion has fallen down to 23 percent. Within domestic debt, the share of interest payments on unfounded and permanent debt have increased over time while the significance of provincial interest payments has declined.

 

Ø      From the policy desk now the strategy will have to be geared towards interest payments on domestic debt both because of the gravity of the problem and the relatively higher scope of improvements on the domestic side.

Ø      At the least now the policy goal must be to keep the public debt to GDP ratio constant. Otherwise, there is the danger that a rising ratio coupled with higher interest rates, accompanying the process of financial sector liberalization would make the situation unsustainable.

Ø      The key policy objective of fiscal management must therefore be to keep the primary budget deficit at a level, which prevents the public debt to GDP ratio from rising.

Ø      (As for the external debt) the exchange rate policy will have to be motivated not only by the consideration of keeping current account deficits at a sustainable level but also by the need to limit capital losses on external debt which increase debt servicing obligations in Ruppee terms.

Ø      Thus based on the above considerations the Swender equation can be a tool to ensure that the public debt to GDP ratio does not rise beyond the present level. (If change in D/Y = 0), thus if the primary budget deficit remains below 1.5 percent of the GDP annually then the public debt to GDP ratio is unlikely to rise significantly beyond its current level (see Appendix I). However, the degree of structural adjustment in public finances may not be adequate if the intention is to keep the level of interest payments to GDP constant.[10] Thus, there would be a need to target a broader definition of these adjustments.

 

Issues and Strategies for Future debt management:

  

 

 

 

 

Risk

 

Description

 

Market Risk[12]

 

Refers to the risks associated with changes in market prices, such as interest rates, exchange rates, commodity prices, on the cost of the government's debt servicing. For both domestic and foreign currency debt, changes in interest rates affect debt servicing costs on new issues when fixed-rate debt is refinanced, and on floating-rate debt at the rate reset dates. Hence, short- duration debt (short-term or floating-rate) is usually considered to be more risky than long-term, fixed rate debt. (Excessive concentration in very long-term, fixed rate debt also can be risky as future financing requirements are uncertain.) Debt denominated in or indexed to foreign currencies also adds volatility to debt servicing costs as measured in domestic currency owing to exchange rate movements. Bonds with embedded put options can exacerbate market and rollover risks.

 

 

 

 

 

 

Rollover Risk

 

The risk that debt will have to be rolled over at an unusually high cost or, in extreme cases, cannot be rolled over at all. To the extent that rollover risk is limited to the risk that debt might have to be rolled over at higher interest rates, including changes in credit spreads, it may be considered a type of market risk. However, because the inability to roll over debt and/or exceptionally large increases in government funding costs can lead to, or exacerbate, a debt crisis and thereby cause real economic losses, in addition to the purely financial effects of higher interest rates, it is often treated separately. Managing this risk is particularly important for emerging market countries.

 

Liquidity Risk

 

There are two types of liquidity risk. One refers to the cost or penalty investors face in trying to exit a position when the number of transactors has decreased or because of the lack of depth of a particular market. This risk is particularly relevant in cases where debt management includes the management of liquid assets or the use of derivatives contracts (State Bank of Pakistan is now considering the Debt-Equity swaps in order to better hedge against such risk). The other form of liquidity risk, for a borrower, refers to a situation where the volume of liquid assets can diminish quickly in the face of unanticipated cash flow obligations and/or a possible difficulty in raising cash through borrowing in a short period of time.

 

Credit Risk

 

The risk of non performance by borrowers on loans or other financial assets or by a counter party on financial contracts. This risk is particularly relevant in cases where debt management includes the management of liquid assets. It may also be relevant in the acceptance of bids in auctions of securities issued by the government as well as in relation to contingent liabilities, and in derivative contracts entered into by the debt manager.

 

Settlement Risk

 

Refers to the potential loss that the government, as a counter party, could suffer as a result of failure to settle, for whatever reason other than default, by another counter party.

 

Operational Risk

 

This includes a range of different types of risks, including transaction errors in the various stages of executing and recording transactions; inadequacies or failures in internal controls, or in systems and services; reputation risk; legal risk; security breaches; or natural disasters that affect business activity.

 Thus, it is imperative for the authorities as for now to take care of different types of risks involved when considering the feasibility of perpetual interest payments involved.

 

 

 Transparency and Accountability:

The allocation of responsibilities among the ministry of finance, the central bank, or a separate debt management agency, for debt management policy advice, and for undertaking primary debt issues, secondary market arrangements, depository facilities, and clearing and settlement arrangements for trade in government securities, should be publicly disclosed. The objectives for debt management should be clearly defined and publicly disclosed, and the measures of cost and risk that are adopted should be explained.[15] The public should be provided with information on the past, current, and projected budgetary activity, including its financing, and the consolidated financial position of the government. The government should regularly publish information on the stock and composition of its debt and financial assets, including their currency, maturity, and interest rate structure. External auditors should audit debt management activities annually.

            Institutional Framework

The legal framework should clarify the authority to borrow and to issue new debt, invest, and undertake transactions on the government's behalf. The organizational framework for debt management should be well specified, and ensure that mandates and roles are well articulated. Risks of government losses from inadequate operational controls should be managed according to sound and prudent practices, including well-articulated responsibilities for staff, and clear monitoring and control policies and reporting arrangements. Debt management activities should be supported by an accurate and comprehensive management information system with proper safeguards.

Staff involved in debt management should be subject to a code-of-conduct and conflict-of-interest guidelines regarding the management of their personal financial affairs. Sound business recovery procedures should be in place to lessen the risk that debt management activities might be severely disrupted by natural disasters, social unrest, or acts of terrorism. The risks inherent in the structure of the government's debt should be carefully monitored and evaluated. These risks should be mitigated to the extent feasible by modifying the debt structure, taking into account the cost of doing so. In order to help guide borrowing decisions and reduce the government's risk, debt managers should consider the financial and other risk characteristics of the government's cash flows (e.g. see appendix II). Debt managers should carefully assess and manage the risks associated with foreign-currency and short-term or floating rate debt.

There should be cost-effective cash management policies in place to enable the authorities to meet with a high degree of certainty their financial obligations as they fall due. A framework should be developed to enable debt managers to identify and manage the trade-offs between expected cost and risk in the government debt portfolio. To assess risk, debt managers should regularly conduct stress tests of the debt portfolio on the basis of the economic and financial shocks to which the government--and the country more generally--are potentially exposed. Debt managers who seek to manage actively the debt portfolio to profit from expectations of movements in interest rates and exchange rates, which differ from those implicit in current market prices, should be aware of the risks involved and accountable for their actions.

Debt managers should consider the impact that contingent liabilities have on the government's financial position, including its overall liquidity, when making borrowing decisions. [16]  In order to minimize cost and risk over the medium to long run, debt managers should ensure that their policies and operations are consistent with the development of an efficient government securities market. The government should strive to achieve a broad investor base for its domestic and foreign obligations, with due regard to cost and risk, and should treat investors equitably. Debt management operations in the primary market should be transparent and predictable. To the extent possible, debt issuance should use market-based mechanisms, including competitive auctions and syndications. Governments and central banks should promote the development of resilient secondary markets that can function effectively under a wide range of market conditions.

We close in on the paper by a very striking picture of Pakistan economy shown in an article of the Daily News, that demands much more efforts than policy recommendations by  the executives, and what is more to say accept the very fact that if our executioners make a delay, this debt burden is indeed bound to sink the next generations to come.

                                                                                                                        Text Box: The latest staff report of the International Monetary Fund, which has given a cross-country analysis of all the low and middle-income countries, South Asia region and HIPCs, clearly depicts that Pakistan should seek debt forgiveness from the official bilateral creditors to stabilise its external sector, as statistics show strange similarities with the HIPCs' economic vulnerabilities. According to the IMF statistics for 1990-98, Pakistan's total debt servicing and interest payments on foreign loans were the highest among all income groups. In 1998, Pakistan paid 12.5 per cent of its GNP on debt servicing alone. This average for low-income countries (where Pakistan is currently categorised) was 3.1 per cent, for all developing countries it averaged 4.5 per cent, for South Asia 2.5 per cent and for HIPC it was just 4.4 per cent. In the case of interest payments on foreign loans, Pakistan consumed 2.8 per cent of its GNP during 1998. This average for low-income countries was 1.3 per cent and for HIPC it was 1.7 per cent of GNP. Pakistan has gradually lost its foreign exchange earning capacity in recent years leading to more dependence on foreign debts. The share of Pakistani exports in the world has declined from 0.22 per cent to 0.15 per cent, foreign direct investment (FDI) is shying away and remittances of overseas workers have substantially fallen in recent years. The regain of this loss would mean an additional amount of $5 billion per annum, and reliance on external debts would decline to the same magnitude. Rising burden of interest payments in the budget from two per cent of GDP in 1980 to well over seven per cent of GDP, against the backdrop of slow growth in revenues in 1990s, has squeezed development spending enormously. As a result, poverty and unemployment are also rising. The latest estimates suggest that 34 per cent people are living below the poverty line of one-dollar-a-day, and on two-dollar-a-day basis 85 per cent population falls below poverty line. 																	-------------The news

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Appendix 1

Analysis of factors contributing to the growth in External Debt

 

 

Dependent Variable: EDEBT

Method: Least Squares

Date: 05/19/01   Time: 19:42

Sample(adjusted): 1981 1999

Included observations: 17 after adjusting endpoints

Convergence achieved after 4 iterations

Variable

 

Coefficient

 

Std. Error

 

t-Statistic

 

Interest payment on External debt

 

46.05405

 

2.638336

 

17.45572

 

Exchange rate

 

0.105785

 

0.061146

 

1.730035

 

Non interest current a/c deficit

 

0.204179

 

0.172592

 

1.183014

 

C

 

-291330.9

 

111611.7

 

-2.610218

 

 

Where:

R-squared

                                              0.988027 (perfect at ‘1’)

Adjusted R-squared

0.984036

S.E. of regression

49282.95

Sum squared resid

2.91E+10

Log likelihood

-204.8520

Durbin-Watson stat

                                                       1.91  (round at ‘2’)

 

Result:

 Total Burden of External Debt = -291331     (+46.1)Eint.    (+0.11)Exc      (+0.2)CD       

 C (intercept) = -291331

Eint = Interest payments on the External Debt.

Exc = (effect of ) Real implied Exchange rate.

CD = (non interest) current account deficit.

Where all three variables positively affected the overall External debt but, only “interest payment on External debt” stands statistically significant at a t-statistic of 17.46. Other parameters led to only marginal effects on the external debt during the period 1981-99.

 

Analysis of factors contributing to the growth in Domestic Debt

 

Dependent Variable: DDEBT

Method: Least Squares

Date: 05/13/01   Time: 09:13

Sample(adjusted): 1981 1998

 

Variable                 Coefficient        Std.Error         t-Statistic

INFLATION

1.709480

           0.127921           13.36359

Interest Payment

on domestic debt               6.874013             0.389932           17.6287               

Primary Budget Deficit    0.912364             0.398697           2.288366

 

Results:

Total Burden of Domestic Debt = 133640.7  (+1.71) Inf.*   (+6.87) D.Int.  (+0.91) PBD

 

Where R2, the goodness of fit = 0.99 (Perfect fit);

Durban-Watson-Statistics = 1.99 (Almost equal to 2, which implies no Positive Autocorrelation).

*Inf. = Inflation as expressed by GDP Deflator.

D.Int. = Interest Payment on domestic debt.

PBD = Primary Budget Deficit.

C (intercept) = 133640.7

All three variables are statistically yielding a positive significance as indicated by the t-statistic.

 

For elucidating our empirical analysis, it is imperative that we also investigate the correlating effects with in the variables themselves, so as to judge the future pattern and base our estimating which is isolated from divergent effects. Following are the correlation matrices of the independent and dependent variables

 

Correlation Matrix for the variable affecting External Debt

 

 

External debt

Exchange rate

Inflation

Interest payments on External debt

Non-interest current a/c deficit

External debt

 1.000000

-0.760203

 0.993961

 0.990318

-0.440704

Exchange rate

-0.760203

 1.000000

-0.786988

-0.809761

 0.515352

Inflation

 0.993961

-0.786988

 1.000000

 0.997317

-0.481485

Interest payment on external debt

 0.990318

-0.809761

 0.997317

 1.000000

-0.489597

Non interest current account deficit

-0.440704

 0.515352

-0.481485

-0.489597

 1.000000

 

 

Correlation Matrix for the variables affecting Foreign Debt

 

 

Domestic Debt

Primary budget deficits

 

Inflation

Interest payment on domestic debt

Domestic Debt

 1.000000

 0.675344

 0.997181

 0.989475

Primary budget deficits

 0.675344

 1.000000

 0.666702

 0.699979

Inflation

 0.997181

 0.666702

 1.000000

 0.992020

Interest payment on domestic debt

 0.989475

 0.699979

 0.992020

 1.000000

 

Debt expressions as in Descriptive Statistics

  

 Mean

External debt

Non interest current a/c deficit

Interest payment on external debt

Inflation

Exchange rate

 Median

 510916.9

-56833.78

 16315.10

 649210.5

 1321089.

 Maximum

 328900.0

-26504.44

 12200.00

 541000.0

 1141400.

 Minimum

 1581900.

 353.5650

 50500.00

 1335000.

 2015300.

 Std. Dev.

 73900.00

-332416.6

 2300.000

 287000.0

 980900.0

 Skewness Kurtosis

 459217.2

 80297.72

 13190.33

 320423.6

 369281.0

 

 1.036670

-2.482300

 1.070089

 0.832729

 0.663800

 

 2.924087

 8.879036

 3.349910

 2.472591

 1.761309

Jarque-Bera  Probability

 3.407732

 44.40774

 3.918998

 2.416098

 2.610026

 

 0.181979

 0.000000

 0.140929

 0.298780

 0.271169

 Observations

19

18

20

19

19

 

 

Domestic Debt

Primary budget deficit

Interest payments on domestic debt

Inflation

 Mean

 510284.2

-6895.000

 63205.00

 649210.5

 Median

 378300.0

-10250.00

 36150.00

 541000.0

 Maximum

 1452700.

 60800.00

 194000.0

 1335000.

 Minimum

 60100.00

-39200.00

 3400.000

 287000.0

 Std. Dev.

 413493.0

 24372.43

 63856.81

 320423.6

 Skewness Kurtosis

 0.821515

 1.556006

 0.958439

 0.832729

 

 2.614239

 5.066422

 2.565540

 2.472591

 Jarque-Bera Probability

 2.254950

 11.62893

 3.219317

 2.416098

 

 0.323850

 0.002984

 0.199956

 0.298780

Observations

19

20

20

19

  

                                                                                                            Appendix II

                                               

Public debt Instruments

Rate of return

Maturity period

Federal investment bonds

13% for three years

3,5 and 10 years

Prize Bonds

-

Min. two month holding for prize eligibility.

Defense Savings Certificate

16% for 10 years

10 years

Special Savings Certificates

15% for first two years, 17% for third year

3 years

Khas Deposit Certificates

12% for first two years 14% for third year

3 years

Savings Accounts

11% per annum

-

Mahana Amdani Account

Monthly return

5 years

R.I. Certificates

14.65% per annum

5 years

 


[1] Excessive levels of debt that result in higher interest rates can have adverse effects on real output. See for      example: A. Alesina, M. de Broeck, A. Prati, and G. Tabellini, "Default Risk on Government Debt in OECD Countries," in Economic Policy: A European Forum (October 1992), pp. 428-463

[2] Financial Stability Forum, "Report of the Working Group on Capital Flows," April 5, 2000, p. 2.

[3] Remarks by Chairman (Federal reserve bank) Alan Greenspan before the World Bank Group and the International Monetary Fund, Program of Seminars, Washington, D.C., September 27, 1999.

[4] See “External shocks and Domestic adjustments”- Naqvi and Sarmad.

[5] “Trends in Pak. Macroeconomic variables”- Vaqar (Ecovista Online)

[6] Hasan 1999.

[7] In calculating the magnitude of the factors this model (which will now be applied to the Pakistani data), assumes the non-interest current account deficit as the residual. Therefore, this is net of private capital inflows and changes in foreign exchange reserves, which constitute other mechanisms, besides borrowing, for financing the deficit.

[8] State bank annual report 1995

[9] Eviews 3.0 version used for estimation. Results confirmed in SPSS 10.0 version.

[10] Also, see Pasha 1996.

[11] “The debt overhang” _ Schroder.

[12] IMF: 67:21, shocks, crises, and the debt management.

[13] Commission for Islamization has already proposed this kind of option to hedge against any further loss.

[14] Pervez 1999. Pervez Hassan is also the Chairman of the Debt Management Committee of Pakistan.

[15] World Bank Policy Reforms.

[16] See also Planning Commissions report on Debt Crises.


By: Vaqar Ahmed


Back