Home Feedback

 

Emancipation and Pomeshchiki

 

In understanding the abolition of serfdom in Russia, one of the main sources of distinction among the historians is the Soviet historians’ tendency and insistency to evaluate the emancipation and the events leading to the emancipation from an ideological perspective. The language they use, frequent quotations from Lenin and Stalin, their search for revolutionary items in the emancipation are the basic indicators of their ideological perspective. With this perspective, Zaionchkovsky describes the period as a transition from autocracy towards bourgeois monarchy, at the same time as the clash of capitalism, which had already started to grow in Russia, with the old feudalist system. However, without a socialist ideological view, the general tendency is to assess the emancipation of serfdom with the principles of ‘continuity’ and ‘change’, a need to change the social and political structure of the state, as a result of various developments in time. These various developments, causes of the emancipation, are also a matter of discussion among the historians.

 

Causes of Emancipation

The defeat in the Crimean War and the fear from another Pugashchevshina are the apparent reasons on which there is no discussion. However, mainly because of lack of information, there is a discussion among the historians in evaluating the effect of economics on the abolishment of serfdom.

 

Lyashchenko supports the idea that during the six decades of the 19th century before the emancipation, the Russian agriculture did not develop. He adds the negative effect of several famines throughout the country in the same period. On the other hand, Zaionchkovsky opposes the argument that agricultural production was worsening before the abolishment of serfdom. Although the two Soviet historians seem to support opposing arguments, they have a common understanding of the Russian economy in the mentioned period: The capitalist economy had already started to develop in the Russian city in the beginning of the century. This brought the clash of feudalism with capitalism. The relationship between the village and the town forced the pomeshchiki for producing excessive grain, which meant more and harsher exploitation of the serf. That is how the serfdom as a system came into a crisis.

 

While Lyashchenko takes the forced production of excessive grain as a cause of the stagnation in the agricultural productivity, Zaionchkovsky explains the economic development in the same period despite the negative effect of serfdom, with the development of capitalism. Besides, Field has a slightly different approach. Accepting the problem in the serf economy, he explains the decline in agricultural productivity by the backwardness of Russian agricultural techniques. He argues, “the servile economy was in crisis, but not a crisis of attitudes”. His argument is that the economy maintained itself, the problems in agricultural productivity were overcome, but the pomeshchik was not satisfied. He had to find additional means of financial support to continue his life on a certain level of prosperity. However, this dissatisfaction dragged the pomeshchiki in a situation, which Robinson describes as ‘desperate’.

 

Leaving aside the general economic indicators in Russia, some simple evidence points out how economy effected the abolishment of serfdom. The pomeshchik was under the heavy burden of credit debts. As a result of heavy debts, pomeshchik’s main way to recover was to force his serfs for excessive production.

 

At this point it is necessary to emphasize the strong authority of the pomeshchik in the village. It is possible to observe the extension of his authority in his interference even in the age for serf marriage. Keeping in mind that complaining the landowner to an upper authority was forbidden, the serf had nothing to do but obey the orders of his landlord. Pomeshchik’s enforcement of the peasantry did not help him pay the loans. So, in the period just before the reform, pomeshchiki were suffering.

 

Lyashchenko, as an evidence for his argument that the feudal agriculture was in a problematic situation, mentions the severe crop failures and famine, which at least 5 times struck the country. Under such conditions, it is hard to think that peasantry was prosperous. Considering the increasing pressure of the landowner, it is obvious that the economic difficulties had an impact in the crisis of the serfdom.

 

Pomeshchiki Position on Emancipation

 Another point of discussion among the historians is the serfowners’ position as to the emancipation. Blum’s argument is that the attitude of the serfowners barred the reform, until when the defeat in the Crimean War made it inevitable and irresistible. Field, also, takes the same idea that serfholders, defining themselves with their serfs, wanted to preserve the old system. However, Emmons makes a long emphasis on the ‘abolitionist sentiment’ among the pomeshchiki. He argues that, just before the Crimean War, abolition of serfdom rapidly spread among the pomeshchiki, who increasingly believed in that serfdom, rather than being a necessary condition for existence, barred their wealth. Counting the reasons for ‘abolitionist sentiment’, Emmons first mentions the fear of a peasant revolt.

 

The increasing number of peasant disturbances between 1826-1829, indicated by Ignatovich (in his article “Peasant Disturbances”) and Lyashchenko’s map of the peasant outbreaks between 1827-1860 give an idea on the contemporary atmosphere of the pomeshchik-serf relations. Zaionchkovsky, trying to stress the revolutionary character of these peasant movements, mentions that according to the Ministry of Internal Affairs, “139 provincial lords and estate managers were killed and seventy attempted murders, between 1836 and 1851”. Although it is hard to conclude as Zaionchkovsky that the peasant movement would likely to become a threat against the existence of the autocratic state, the numbers mentioned would help pomeshchiki understand Alexander II, when he said: “It were better that the emancipation came from above, than from below.”

 

Another point, which Emmons proposes to be a factor in abolitionist sentiment among the pomeshchiki, is the mortgage payments. Although Chichikov tries to buy ‘dead souls’ to benefit by mortgaging them (‘dead souls’ also refers to the landowners selling their ‘dead souls’), it becomes burdensome when the souls are alive. Just before the reform, two-thirds of all the serfs had been mortgaged to the state institutions. Although Stuve argues that these mortgage loans were invested in agricultural technology, Field and Robinson oppose him, claiming that the loans simply evaporated as luxurious expenditures. At least it turned out to be that the loans were not expended in a way that would bring it back. At the same time, Field says that the indebtedness of the pomeshchiki is not necessarily connected with the emancipation. However, Emmons supports his argument with several landowner and peasant proposals, which reached the government, referring to the indebtedness of the pomeshchiki as an incentive for emancipation.

 

Beyond getting rid of their debts, the idea of employing hired labor appealed more to some landowners. Besides, for some of them, receiving a considerable amount of money made emancipation more appealing to them. Robinson also mentions the existence of such landowners, willing emancipation in order to profit from it.

 

Emmons talks about the role of enlightenment in the spread of the abolitionist sentiment. The educated members of the society, affected from the liberal ideology, increasingly supported emancipation, spreading their ideas. This group is also mentioned by the other historians as intellectuals (Blum) or intelligentsia (Zaionchkovsky).

 

Considering the pomeshchiki attitude toward emancipation, another issue, which has been discussed by the historians, is the effect of geographical location on provincial committees’ choices on how much land should be given to the peasants. Examining the proposals of the committees on the size of peasant holdings and on redemption payments, Blum argues that, too much emphasis was made on geographical considerations of the committees. He accuses Kornilov and his “dogmatic followers” for overlooking many exceptions in which committees gave their decisions considering some other factors.  He seems to be right as Emmons and Lyashchenko make the generalization that in northern and central non-black soil regions, where obrok was preferred to land, the committees tended to leave relatively more land to the peasants than the committees in the fertile but low-populated regions. Although Lyashchenko makes the generalization roughly and does not go into detail, Emmons is more careful in reflecting the details and quotes Kornilov when he also mentions the exceptions. While Emmons’s special emphasis on the ‘liberal committees’ partly saves himself from Blum’s accusation, Lyashchenko, though is not a Kornilov follower, cannot avoid it.