The propaganda model revisited

Monthly Review, July, 1996
by Edward S. Herman

In Manufacturing Consent: The Political Economy of
the Mass Media (Pantheon, 1988) Noam Chomsky and I
put forward a "propaganda model" as a framework for
analyzing and understanding how the mainstream U.S.
media work and why they perform as they do. We had
long been impressed with the regularity with which
the media operate within restricted assumptions,
depend heavily and uncritically on elite information
sources, and participate in propaganda campaigns
helpful to elite interests. In trying to explain why
they do this we looked for structural factors as the
only possible root of systematic behavior and
performance patterns.

The propaganda model was and is in distinct contrast
to the prevailing mainstream explanations -- both
liberal and conservative--of media behavior and
performance. These approaches downplay structural
factors, generally presupposing their unimportance
or positive impact because of the multiplicity of
agents and thus competition and diversity. Liberal
and conservative analysts emphasize journalistic
conduct, public opinion, and news source initiatives
as the main determining variables. The analysts are
inconsistent in this regard, however. When they
discuss media systems in communist or other
authoritarian states, the idea that journalists or
public opinion can override the power of those who
own and control the media is dismissed as nonsense
and even considered an apology for tyranny. There
is a distinct difference, too, between the political
implications of the propaganda model and mainstream
scholarship. If structural factors shape the broad
contours of media performance, and if that performance
is incompatible with a truly democratic political
culture, then a basic change in media ownership,
organization, and purpose is necessary for the
achievement of genuine democracy. In mainstream
analyses such a perspective is politically unacceptable,
and its supportive arguments and evidence are rarely
subject to debate.

In this article I will describe the propaganda model,
address some of the criticism that has been leveled
against it, and discuss how the model holds up nearly
a decade after its publication.1 I will also provide
some examples of how the propaganda model can help
explain the nature of media coverage of important
political topics in the 1990s.

The Propaganda Model

What is the propaganda model and how does it work? The
crucial structural factors derive from the fact that
the dominant media are firmly imbedded in the market
system. They are profit-seeking businesses, owned by
very wealthy people (or other companies); they are
funded largely by advertisers who are also profit-seeking
entities, and who want their ads to appear in a supportive
selling environment. The media are also dependent on
government and major business firms as information sources,
and both efficiency and political considerations, and
frequently overlapping interests, cause a certain degree
of solidarity to prevail among the government, major media,
and other corporate businesses. Government and large
non-media business firms are also best positioned (and
sufficiently wealthy) to be able to pressure the media
with threats of withdrawal of advertising or TV licenses,
libel suits, and other direct and indirect modes of attack.
The media are also constrained by the dominant ideology,
which heavily featured anticommunism before and during
the Cold War era, and was mobilized often to prevent the
media from criticizing attacks on small states labelled
communist.

These factors are linked together, reflecting the
multi-leveled capability of powerful business and
government entities and collectives (e.g., the Business
Roundtable; U.S. Chamber of Commerce; industry lobbies
and front groups) to exert power over the flow of
information. We noted that the five factors involved --
ownership, advertising, sourcing, flak, and anticommunist
ideology -- work as "filters" through which information
must pass, and that individually and often in additive
fashion they help shape media choices. We stressed that
the filters work mainly by the independent action of many
individuals and organizations; these frequently, but not
always, share a common view of issues and similar interests.
In short, the propaganda model describes a decentralized
and non-conspiratorial market system of control and
processing, although at times the government or one or
more private actors may take initiatives and mobilize
coordinated elite handling of an issue.

Propaganda campaigns can occur only when consistent with
the interests of those controlling and managing the filters.
For example, these managers all accepted the view that the
Polish government's crackdown on the Solidarity union in
1980-81 was extremely newsworthy and deserved severe
condemnation; whereas the same interests did not find the
Turkish military government's equally brutal crackdown on
trade unions in Turkey at about the same time to be
newsworthy or reprehensible. In the latter case the U.S.
government and business community liked the military
government's anticommunist stance and open door economic
policy; and the crackdown on Turkish unions had the merit
of weakening the Left and keeping wages down. In the Polish
case, propaganda points could be scored against a
Soviet-supported government, and concern could be expressed
for workers whose wages were not paid by Free World
employers! The fit of this dichotomization to corporate
interests and anticommunist ideology is obvious.

We used the concepts of "worthy" and "unworthy" victims to
describe this dichotomization, with a trace of irony, as the
differential treatment was clearly related to political and
economic advantage rather than anything like actual worth.
In fact, the Polish trade unionists quickly ceased to be
worthy when communism was overthrown and the workers were
struggling against a western-oriented neoliberal regime.
The travails of Polish workers now, like those of Turkish
workers, do not pass through the propaganda model filters.
They are both unworthy victims at this point.

We never claimed that the propaganda model explains everything
or that it shows media omnipotence and complete effectiveness
in manufacturing consent. It is a model of media behavior
and performance, not media effects. We explicitly pointed to
alternative media, grass roots information sources, and public
skepticism about media veracity as important limits on media
effectiveness in propaganda service, and we urged the support
and more effective use of these alternatives. We have
frequently pointed to the general public's disagreement with
the media and elite over the morality of the Vietnam War and
the desirability of the assault on Nicaragua in the 1980s
(among other matters). The power of the U.S. propaganda
system lies in its ability to mobilize an elite consensus,
to give the appearance of democratic consent, and to create
enough confusion, misunderstanding, and apathy in the general
population to allow elite programs to go forward. We also
emphasized the fact that there are often differences within
the elite that open up space for some debate and even
occasional (but very rare) attacks on the intent, as well
as the tactical means of achieving elite ends.

Although the propaganda model was generally well received
on the Left, some complained of an allegedly pessimistic
thrust and implication of hopeless odds to be overcome.
A closely related objection was its inapplicability to local
conflicts where the possibility of effective resistance was
greater. But the propaganda model does not suggest that local
and even larger victories are impossible, especially where
the elites are divided or have limited interest in an issue.
For example, coverage of issues like gun control, school
prayer, and abortion rights may well receive more varied
treatment than, say, global trade, taxation, and economic
policy. Moreover, well organized campaigns by labor, human
rights, or environmental organizations fighting against
abusive local businesses can sometimes elicit positive media
coverage. In fact, we would like to think that the
propaganda model even suggests where and how activists can
best deploy their efforts to influence mainstream media
coverage of issues.

The model does suggest that the mainstream media, as elite
institutions, commonly frame news and allow debate only within
the parameters of elite interests; and that where the elite
is really concerned and unified, and/or where ordinary citizens
are not aware of their own stake in an issue or are
immobilized by effective propaganda, the media will serve
elite interests uncompromisingly.

Mainstream Liberal and Academic "Left" Critiques

Many liberals and a number of academic media analysts of the
left did not like the propaganda model. Some of them found
repugnant a wholesale condemnation of a system in which they
played a respected role; for them it is a basically sound
system, its inequalities of access regrettable but tolerable,
its pluralism and competition effectively responding to
consumer demands. In the postmodernist mode, global analyses
and global solutions are rejected and derided; individual
struggles and small victories are stressed, even by nominally
leftist thinkers.

Many of the critiques displayed barely-concealed anger; and
in most the propaganda model was dismissed with a few
superficial cliches (conspiratorial, simplistic, etc.)
without minimal presentation of the model or subjecting it
to the test of evidence. Let me discuss briefly some of the
main criticisms.

Conspiracy theory. We explained in Manufacturing Consent that
critical analyses like ours would inevitably elicit cries of
conspiracy theory, and in a futile effort to prevent this we
devoted several pages of the Preface to showing that the
propaganda model is best described as a "guided market
system," and explicitly rejecting conspiracy. Mainstream
critics still could not abandon the charge, partly because
they knew that falsely accusing a radical critique of
conspiracy theory would not cost them anything and partly
because of their superficial assumption that since the media
comprise thousands of "independent" journalists and companies
any finding that they follow a "party line" serving the state
must rest on an assumed conspiracy. (In fact it can result
from a widespread gullible acceptance of official handouts,
common internalized beliefs, fear of reprisal for critical
analysis, etc.). The propaganda model explains media behavior
and performance in structural terms, and intent is an
unmeasurable red herring. All we know is that the media and
journalists mislead in tandem -- some no doubt internalize
a propaganda line as true, some may know it is false, but the
point is unknowable and irrelevant.

Failure to take account of media professionalism and objectivity.
Communications professor Dan Hallin argued that we failed to
take account of the maturing of journalist professionalism,
which he claimed to be "central to understanding how the media
operate." (Keeping America On Top of the World, 13) Hallin also
stated that in protecting and rehabilitating the public sphere
"professionalism is surely part of the answer."(4)

But professionalism and objectivity rules are fuzzy, flexible,
and superficial manifestations of deeper power and control
relationships. Professionalism arose in journalism in the years
when the newspaper business was becoming less competitive and
more dependent on advertising. Professionalism was not an
antagonistic movement by the workers against the press owners,
but was actively encouraged by many of the latter. It gave a
badge of legitimacy to journalism, ostensibly assuring readers
that the news would not be influenced by the biases of owners,
advertisers, or the journalists themselves. In certain
circumstances it has provided a degree of autonomy, but
professionalism has also internalized some of the commercial
values that media owners hold most dear, like relying on
inexpensive official sources as the credible news source. As
Ben Bagdikian has noted, professionalism has made journalists
oblivious to the compromises with authority they are constantly
making. Even Hallin acknowledges that professional journalism
can allow something close to complete government control via
sourcing domination.

While Hallin claimed that the propaganda model cannot explain
the case of media coverage of the Central American wars of the
1980s, where there was considerable domestic hostility to the
Reagan policies, in fact the propaganda model works extremely
well there, whereas Hallin's focus on "professionalism" fails
abysmally. Hallin acknowledged that "the administration was
able more often than not to prevail in the battle to determine
the dominant frame of television coverage," (64) "the broad
patterns in the framing of the story can be accounted for
almost entirely by the evolution of policy and elite debate
in Washington," (74) and "coherent statements of alternative
visions of the world order and U.S. policy rarely appeared in
the news."(77) This is exactly what the propaganda model would
forecast. And if, as Hallin contended, a majority of the public
opposed the elite view, what kind of "professionalism" allows a
virtually complete suppression of the issues as the majority
perceives them?

Hallin mentions a "nascent alternative perspective" in reporting
on El Salvador -- a "human rights" framework -- that "never caught
hold." The propaganda model can explain why it never took hold;
Hallin does not. With 700 journalists present at the Salvadoran
election of 1982, allegedly "often skeptical" of election
integrity, (72) why did it yield a "public relations victory"
for the administration and a major falsification of reality (as
described in Manufacturing Consent)? Hallin did not explain
this. He never mentioned the Office of Public Diplomacy or the
firing of reporter Raymond Bonner and the work of the flak
machines. He never explained the failure of the media to report
even a tiny fraction of the crimes of the contras in Nicaragua
and the death machines of El Salvador and Guatemala, in contrast
with their inflation of Sandinista misdeeds and double standard
in reporting on the Nicaraguan election of 1984. Given the elite
divisions and public hostility to the Reagan policy, media
subservience was phenomenal and arguably exceeded that which
the propaganda model might have anticipated.2

Failure to explain continued opposition and resistance. Both
Hallin and historian Walter LaFeber (in a review in the New York
Times) pointed to the continued opposition to Reagan's Central
America policy as somehow incompatible with the model. These
critics failed to comprehend that the propaganda model is about
how the media work, not how effective they are. By the logic of
this form of criticism, as many Soviet citizens did not swallow
the lines put forward by Pravda, this demonstrates that Pravda
was not serving a state propaganda function.

Propaganda model too mechanical, functionalist, ignores existence
of space, contestation, and interaction. This set of criticisms
is at the heart of the negative reactions of the serious
left-of-center media analysts such as Philip Schlesinger, James
Curran, Peter Golding, Graham Murdoch, and John Eldridge, as
well as of Dan Hallin. Of these critics, only Schlesinger both
summarizes the elements of our model and discusses our evidence.
He acknowledges that the case studies make telling points, but
in the end he finds ours "a highly deterministic vision of how
the media operate coupled with a straightforward functionalist
conception of ideology" (Media, Culture and Society, 1989).
Specifically, we failed to explain the weights to be given our
five filters; we did not allow for external influences, nor did
we offer a "thoroughgoing analysis of the ways in which economic
dynamics operate to structure both the range and form of press
presentations" (quoting Graham Murdoch); and while putting forward
"a powerful effects model" we admit that the system is not
all-powerful, which calls into question our determinism.

The criticism of the propaganda model for being deterministic
ignores several important considerations. Any model involves
deterministic elements, so that this is a straw person unless the
critics also show that the system is not logically consistent,
operates on false premises, or that the predictive power of the
determining variables is poor. The critics often acknowledge
that the case studies we present are powerful, but they do not
show where the alleged determinism leads to error nor do they
offer or point to alternative models that would do a better job.3

The propaganda model is dealing with extraordinarily complex sets
of events, and only claims to offer a broad framework of analysis
that requires modification depending on many local and special
factors, and may be entirely inapplicable in some cases. But if
it offers insight in numerous important cases that have large
effects and cumulative ideological force, it is defensible unless
a better model is provided. Usually the critics wisely stick to
generalities and offer no critical detail or alternative model;
when they do provide alternatives, the results are not impressive.4

The criticism of the propaganda model for functionalism is also
dubious and the critics sometimes seem to call for more
functionalism. The model does describe a system in which the
media serve the elite, but by complex processes incorporated into
the model as means whereby the powerful protect their interests
naturally and without overt conspiracy. This would seem one of
the propaganda model's merits; it shows a dynamic and
self-protecting system in operation. The same corporate
community that influences the media through its power as owner,
dominant funder (advertising), and a major news source also
underwrites Accuracy in Media and the American Enterprise
Institute to influence the media through harassment and the
provision of "sound" experts. Critics of propaganda model
functionalism like Eldridge and Schlesinger contradictorily
point to the merit of analyses that focus on "how sources
organize media strategies" to achieve their ends. Apparently
it is admirable to analyze micro corporate strategies to influence
the media, but to focus on global corporate efforts to influence
the media -- along with the complementary effects of thousands of
local strategies -- is illegitimate functionalism!

It is also untrue that the propaganda model implies no constraints
on media owners/managers. We spell out the conditions affecting
when the media will be relatively open or closed -- mainly
disagreements among the elite and the extent to which other groups
in society are interested in, informed about, and organized to
fight about issues. But the propaganda model does start from the
premise that a critical political economy will put front and
center the analysis of the locus of media control and the
mechanisms by which the powerful are able to dominate the flow
of messages and limit the space of contesting parties. The limits
on their power are certainly important, but why should they get
first place, except as a means of minimizing the power of the
dominant interests, inflating the elements of contestation, and
pretending that the marginalized have more strength than
they really possess?

Enhanced Relevance of the Propaganda Model

The dramatic changes in the economy, communications industries,
and politics over the past decade have tended to enhance the
applicability of the propaganda model. The first two filters --
ownership and advertising -- have become ever more important.
The decline of public broadcasting, the increase in corporate
power and global reach, and the mergers and centralization of
the media, have made bottom line considerations more controlling.
The competition for serving advertisers has become more intense.
Newsrooms have been more thoroughly incorporated into transnational
corporate empires, with shrunken resources and even less management
enthusiasm for investigative journalism that would challenge the
structure of power. In short, the professional autonomy of
journalists has been reduced.

Some argue that the Internet and the new communication technologies
are breaking the corporate stranglehold on journalism and opening
an unprecedented era of interactive democratic media. There is no
evidence to support this view as regards journalism and mass
communication. In fact, one could argue that the new technologies
are exacerbating the problem. They permit media firms to shrink
staff while achieving greater outputs and they make possible
global distribution systems, thus reducing the number of media
entities. Although the new technologies have great potential for
democratic communication, left to the market there is little
reason to expect the Internet to serve democratic ends.

The third and fourth filters -- sourcing and flak -- have also
strengthened as mechanisms of elite influence. A reduction in
the resources devoted to journalism means that those who subsidize
the media by providing sources for copy gain greater leverage.
Moreover, work by people like Alex Carey, John Stauber, and
Sheldon Rampton has helped us see how the public relations industry
has been able to manipulate press coverage of issues on behalf of
corporate America. The PR industry understands how to use
journalistic conventions to serve its own ends. Studies of news
sources reveal that a significant proportion of news originates
in the PR industry. There are, by one conservative count, 20,000
more PR agents working to doctor the news today than there are
journalists writing it.

The fifth filter -- anticommunist ideology -- is possibly weakened
by the collapse of the Soviet Union and global socialism, but this
is easily offset by the greater ideological force of the belief in
the "miracle of the market."(Reagan) There is now an almost religious
faith in the market, at least among the elite, so that regardless of
evidence, markets are assumed benevolent and non-market mechanisms
are suspect. When the Soviet economy stagnated in the 1980s, it was
attributed to the absence of markets; when capitalist Russia
disintegrated in the 1990s it was because politicians and workers
were not letting markets work their magic. Journalism has
internalized this ideology. Adding it to the fifth filter, in a
world where the global power of market institutions makes anything
other than market options seem utopian, gives us an ideological
package of immense strength.

Further Applications

The propaganda model applies exceedingly well to the media's
treatment of the passage of the North American Free Trade Agreement
(NAFTA) and the subsequent Mexican crisis and meltdown of 1994-95.
Once again there was a sharp split between the preferences of
ordinary citizens and the elite and business community, with polls
consistently showing substantial majorities opposed to NAFTA--and
to the bailout of investors in Mexican securities--but the elite
in favor. Media news coverage, selection of "experts," and opinion
columns were skewed accordingly; their judgment was that the
benefits of NAFTA were obvious, agreed to by all qualified
authorities, and that only demagogues and "special interests"
were opposed. Meg Greenfield, Washington Post Op Ed editor
explained the huge imbalance in her opinion column: "On the rare
occasion when columnists of the left, right, and middle are all
in agreement ... I don't believe it is right to create an
artificial balance where none exists." But with a majority of the
public opposing NAFTA, the pro-NAFTA unity among the pundits
simply highlighted the huge elite bias of mainstream punditry.
It may be worth noting that the transnational media corporations
have a distinct self-interest in global trade agreements, as they
are among their foremost beneficiaries.

The pro-corporate and anti-labor bias of the mainstream media was
also evident in the editorial denunciations (both in the New York
Times and Washington Post) of labor's attempt to influence votes
on NAFTA, with no comparable criticism of corporate or governmental
(U.S. and Mexican) lobbying and PR. After having touted the puny
labor and environmental protective side-agreements belatedly added
to NAFTA as admirable, the media then failed to follow up on their
enforcement and, in fact, when labor tried to use their provisions
to prevent attacks on union organization in Mexico, the press
ignored the case or derided it as labor "aggression."5 With the
Mexican meltdown beginning in December 1994, the media were clear
that NAFTA was not to blame, and in virtual lock-step they
supported the Mexican (investor) bailout, despite poll reports
of massive general public opposition. Experts and media repeatedly
explained that the merit of NAFTA was that it had "locked Mexico
in" so that it could not resort to controls to protect itself
from severe deflation. They were oblivious to the profoundly
undemocratic nature of this lock-in.6

As is suggested by the treatment of NAFTA and labor's right to
participate in its debates, the propaganda model applies to
domestic as well as foreign issues. Labor has been under siege
in the United States for the past fifteen years, but you would
hardly know this from the mainstream media. The decertification
of unions, use of replacement workers, and long and debilitating
strikes like that involving Caterpillar were treated in a very
low key, and in a notable illustration of the applicability
of the propaganda model, the long Pittston miners strike was
accorded much less attention than the strike of miners in the
Soviet Union.7 For years the media found the evidence that the
majority of ordinary citizens were doing badly in the New Economic
Order to be of marginal interest; they "discovered" this issue
only under the impetus of Pat Buchanan's rightwing populist
outcries.

The coverage of the "drug wars" is well explained by the
propaganda model.8 In the health insurance controversy of 1992-93,
the media's refusal to take the single-payer option seriously,
despite apparent widespread public support and the effectiveness
of the system in Canada, served well the interests of the insurance
and medical service complex. The uncritical media reporting and
commentary on the alleged urgency of fiscal restraint and a balanced
budget in the years 1992-96 fit well the business community's desire
to reduce the social budget and weaken regulation, culminating
in the Contract With America.9 The applicability of the propaganda
model in these and other cases seems clear.

Final note

In retrospect, perhaps we should have made it clearer that the
propaganda model was about media behavior and performance, with
uncertain and variable effects. Maybe we should have spelled out
in more detail the contesting forces both within and outside the
media and the conditions under which these are likely to be
influential. But we clearly made these points, and it is quite
possible that nothing we could have done would have prevented our
being labelled conspiracy theorists, rigid determinists, and
deniers of the possibility that people can resist (even as we
called for resistance).

The propaganda model still seems a very workable framework for
analyzing and understanding the mainstream media -- perhaps even
more so than in 1988. As noted earlier in reference to Central
America, it often surpasses expectations of media subservience
to government propaganda. And we are still waiting for our
critics to provide a better model.

    Source: geocities.com/michaelstec