Historical Materialism is the application of Marxist science to
historical development. The fundamental proposition of historical materialism
can be summed up in a sentence: ""it is not the consciousness of men
that determines their existence, but, on the contrary, their social existence
that determines their consciousness." (Marx, in the Preface to A Contribution
to the Critique of Political Economy.)
What does this mean?
Readers of the Daily Mirror (a British daily paper Editor) will
be familiar with the "Perishers" cartoon strip. In one incident the
old dog, Wellington wanders down to a pool full of crabs. The crabs speculate
about the mysterious divinity, the "eyeballs in the sky," which appears
to them.
The point is, that is actually how you would look at things if your
universe were a pond. Your consciousness is determined by your being. Thought
is limited by the range of experience of the species.
We know very little about how primitive people thought, but we know
what they couldn't have been thinking about. They wouldn't have wandered about
wondering what the football results were, for instance. League football
presupposes big towns able to get crowds large enough to pay professional footballers
and the rest of the club staff. Industrial towns in their turn can only emerge
when the productivity of labour has developed to the point where a part of
society can be fed by the rest, and devote themselves to producing other
requirements than food.
In other words, an extensive division of labour must exist. The other
side of this is that people must be accustomed to working for money and buying
the things they want from others-including tickets to the football-which of
course was not the case in primitive society.
So this simple example shows how even things like professional football
are dependent on the way society makes its daily bread, on people's
"social existence".
After all, what is mankind? The great idealist philosopher Hegel
said that "man, is a thinking being." Actually Hegel's view
was a slightly more sophisticated form of the usual religious view that man is
endowed by his Creator with a brain to admire His handiwork.
It is true that thinking is one way we are different from dung
beetles, sticklebacks and lizards. But why did humans develop the capacity to
think?
Over a hundred years ago, Engels pointed out that upright posture
marked the transition from ape to man, a completely materialist explanation.
This view has been confirmed by the most recent researches of anthropologists
such as Leakey.
Upright posture liberated the hands for gripping with an opposable
thumb. This enabled tools to be used and developed.
Upright posture also allowed early humans to rely more on the eyes,
rather than the other senses, for sensing the world around. The use of the
hands developed the powers of the brain through the medium of the eyes.
Engels was a dialectical materialist. In no way did he minimise the
importance of thought-rather he explained how it arose. We can also see
that Benjamin Franklin, the eighteenth-century US politician and inventor, was
much nearer a materialist approach than Hegel when he defined man as a tool-making
animal.
Darwin showed a hundred years ago that there is a struggle for existence,
and species survive through natural selection. At first sight early humans
didn't have a lot going for them, compared with the speed of the cheetah, the
strength of the lion, or the sheer intimidating bulk of the elephant. Yet
humans came to dominate the planet and, more recently, to drive many of these
more fearsome animals to the point of extinction.
What differentiates mankind from the lower animals is that, however
self-reliant animals such as lions may seem, they ultimately just take external
nature around them for granted, whereas, mankind progressively masters nature.
The process whereby mankind masters nature is labour. At Marx's
grave, Engels stated that his friend's great discovery was that "mankind
must first of all eat, drink, have shelter and clothing, and therefore work
before it can pursue politics, science, art, religion etc.
In another dialectical formulation, Engels says that "the hand is
not only the organ of labour, it is also the product of labour."
While we can't read the minds of our primitive human beings, we can
make a pretty good guess about what they were thinking most of the time—food.
The struggle against want has dominated history ever since.
Marxists are often accused of being 'economic determinists'. Actually,
Marxists are far from denying the importance of ideas or the active role of
individuals in history. But precisely because we are active, we understand the limits
of individual activity, and the fact that the appropriate social conditions
must exist before our ideas and our activity can be effective.
Our academic opponents are generally passive cynics who exalt
individual activity amid the port and walnuts from over-stuffed armchairs. We
understand, with Marx that people "make their own history...but under
circumstances directly encountered, given and transmitted from the past".
We need to understand how society is developing in order to intervene in the
process. That is what we mean when we say Marxism is a science of perspectives.
Language, the currency of thought, is itself the creation of labour. We
can see this even among jackals and other hunting animals that rely upon
teamwork rather than just brute force or speed to kill their prey. They have a
series of barked commands and warnings—the beginnings of language.
That is how language evolved among people, as a result of their
co-operative labour. The germs of rational thinking among the higher apes, and
the limited use of tools by some animals, have remained at a beginning stage,
while reaching fruition only in human beings.
We have seen that labour distinguishes mankind from the other
animals—that mankind progressively changes nature through labour, and in doing
so changes itself. It follows that there is a real measure of progress through
all the miseries and pitfalls of human history—the increasing ability of men
and women to master nature and subjugate it to their own requirements: in other
words, the increasing productivity of labour.
To each stage in the development of the productive forces corresponds a
certain set of production relations.
Production relation means the way people organise themselves to gain
their daily bread. Production relations are thus the skeleton of every form of
society. They provide the conditions of social existence that determine human consciousness.
Marx explained how the development of the productive forces brings into
existence different production relations, and different forms of class society.
By a 'class' we mean a group of people in society with the same
relationship to the means of production. The class which owns and controls the
means of production rules society. This, at the same time, enables it to force
the oppressed or labouring class to toil in the rulers' interests. The
labouring class is forced to produce a surplus which the ruling class lives
off.
Marx explained:
"The specific economic form in which unpaid surplus-labour is pumped
out of the direct producers determines the relationship of rulers and ruled, as
it grows directly out of production itself and, in turn, reacts upon it as a
determining element. Upon this, however, is founded the entire formation of the
economic community which grows up out of the production relations themselves;
thereby simultaneously its specific political form. It is always the direct
relationship of the owners of the conditions of production to the direct
producers-a relation always naturally corresponding to a definite stage in the
development of the methods of labour and thereby its social productivity-which
reveals the innermost secret, the hidden basis of the entire social structure,
and with it the political form of the relation of sovereignty and dependence,
in short the corresponding specific form of the state. (Capital, Vol.
III.)
Primitive Communism
In the earliest stages of society people did not go into factories,
work to produce things they would not normally consume, and be 'rewarded' at
the end of the week with pieces of coloured paper or decorated discs which
other people would be quite prepared to accept in exchange for the food,
clothing, etc., which they needed. Such behaviour would have struck our remote
ancestors as quite fantastic.
Nor did many of the other features of modern society we so much take
for granted exist. What socialist has not heard the argument "People are
bound to be greedy and grabbing. You can't get socialism because you can't
change human nature?
In fact, society divided into classes has existed for no more
than about 10,000 years-one hundredth of the time mankind has been on this
planet. For the other 99% of the time there was no class society, that is, no
enforced inequalities, no state, and no family in the modern sense.
This was not because primitive people were unaccountably more noble
than us, but because production relations produced a different sort of society,
and so a different 'human nature'. Being determines consciousness, and if
people's social being changes--if the society they live under changes--then
their consciousness will also change.
The basis of primitive society was gathering and hunting. The only
division of labour was that between men and women for the entirely natural
biological reason that women were burdened much of the time with young
children. They gathered vegetable foods while the men hunted.
Thus each sex played an important part in production. On the basis of
studying tribes such as the !Kung in the Kalahari desert, who still live under
primitive communist conditions, it has been estimated that the female
contribution to the food supply may well have been more important than the
male's.
All these tribal societies had features in common. The hunting grounds
were regarded as the common property of the tribe. How could they be anything
else when hunting itself is a collective activity? The very insecurity of
existence leads to sharing. It's no good hiding a dead hippo from your
mates--you won't be able to eat it before it rots anyway, and there may well
come a time when other tribesmen have a superfluity while you're in distress.
It's common sense to share and share alike.
Private property did exist in personal implements, but in the most
different tribal societies there existed similar rules to burn or bury these
with the body of the owner, in order to prevent the accumulation of inequality.
Even after these tribes began to develop agriculture there was a progressive
redivision of the land, so strong were the norms of primitive communism. The
Roman historian Tacitus noted such rules among the German tribes.
Women were held in high esteem in such societies. They contributed at
least equally to the wealth of the tribe. They developed separate skills--it
seems women invented pottery and even made the crucial breakthrough to
agriculture.
No such institution as the state was necessary, for there were
no fundamental antagonistic class interests tearing society apart. Individual
disputes could be sorted out within the tribe.
Old men with experience certainly played leading parts in the
decision-making of the tribe. They were chiefs, however, and not kings--their
authority was deserved or it did not exist. As late as the third century AD
(when it was ceasing to be true) Athanaric, leader of the German tribe, the
Visigoths, said: "I have authority, not power".
Society developed because it had to. Beginning in tropical Africa, as
population grew to cover more inhospitable parts of the globe, people had to
use their power of thought and labour to develop--or die. From gathering fruit,
nuts, etc., it was a step forward to cultivating the land--actually ensuring
that vegetable food was to hand. From hunting it was a step to husbandry,
penning in the animals. Tribal society remained the norm.
The first great revolution in mankind's history was the agricultural,
or Neolithic revolution. Grains were selected and sown, and the ground ploughed
up with draught animals. For the first time a substantial surplus over
and above the subsistence needs of the toilers came into existence.
Under primitive communism there had been simply no basis for an idle
class. There was no point in enslaving someone else, since they could only
provide for their own needs. Now the possibility arose for idleness for some,
but mankind could still not provide enough for everyone to lead such
a life.
On this basis, class societies arose--societies divided between
possessing and labouring classes.
The main issue in the class struggle down the ages has been the
struggle over the surplus produced by the toilers. The way this surplus was
appropriated--grabbed--depended on the different mode of production inaugurated
by agriculture. This change provided the base for the complete transformation
of social life.
Tribal norms died hard. At first, land was redivided. Even in feudal
Europe, village communities in some areas carried on the traditions of
primitive communism in a transmuted form by redivision of the original peasant
land.
But agriculture, unlike hunting, could be more an individual activity.
By working harder you could get more and, when everyone lived on the margin of
survival, that was important.
Moreover, the agricultural revolution--involving the use of draught
animals in ploughing, etc., mainly handled by men--relegated women to the home,
working up materials provided by the man. It was the lack of a direct role in
production that led to the world--historic defeat of the female sex.
Men wanted to pass on their unequal property to a male heir. In
primitive communist society descent had been traced through the female
line (inheritance had been unimportant). Now inheritance began to be
traced through the male line.
We do not know exactly how class society came into being, but we can
piece together the story from bits of evidence available to us. We call this
process a revolution, and so it was in the profoundest sense of the word.
But we must remember that transitional forms between the different
types of society were in existence for hundreds, perhaps thousands, of years
before the new type definitively replaced the old. Human progress did not
proceed evenly but according to the law of combined and uneven development.
It was not the well-situated people of equatorial Africa, but people in
more temperate climes (probably the near East) who were first forced to develop
agriculture.
The first agriculture was of course very rudimentary, probably
consisting of 'slash and burn' cultivation. This meant that the tribe kept on
the move, for the cleared land offered good crops for only a couple of years
before yields dropped off.
Thus tribal society remained in existence, but underwent modifications.
Tacitus describes the military democracy of the German tribes of his time, with
a constitution of a war chief, councils of elders and assembly of warriors
(women had now been disenfranchised). This was typical for tribes at this stage
of development.
Though the assembly could reject or approve all decisions (by banging
their spears on their shields), in the war chief we see the embryo of a king,
and in the council of elders the outline of a ruling aristocracy.
The landlord rulers of Rome were organised in the senate ("old
men") and the Anglo-Saxon kings were advised by a Witan ("'wise
men"), both relics of a democratic tribal constitution that had been
turned into its opposite. The German tribes were now organised for warfare because
a surplus existed, however precariously, which could be taken unless defended.
Anthropologists such as Leakey have shown that, contrary to the views
of writers such as Desmond Morris (The Naked Ape) and Robert Ardrey (
The Hunting Hypothesis), the human being is not inherently aggressive.
While primitive communist societies engaged in battles, e.g. over scarce
hunting grounds, wars began to be an established and regular feature of
history only at the stage when there was something worth fighting for.
We have spoken of agriculture as being the breakthrough to a society
where a surplus could be produced. In fact the raising of the productivity of
labour made possible by agriculture allowed a more extensive division of
labour--people could turn their hands to producing other things.
So the agricultural revolution brought in its train associated
revolutions in technique (such as in pottery and metal-working) and in the
whole social structure.
Inequalities developed between different tribal peoples as well as
within the tribes. For geographical and other reasons some tribes began to concentrate
on stock rearing, fishing, etc.
As agricultural peoples began to settle down around villages fortified
to protect their surplus (or rather, the surplus some of their number had
acquired) these fishing and stock-rearing peoples took over the job of
exchanging goods. Before, exchange had been a casual act between tribes who met
one another on their travels. Now it became a regular occasion.
Metal was of course one of the most important items of trade. The Jews
were one of the most famous stock-rearing peoples (in the Bible, the wealth of
Abraham is always measured in herds) who developed into traders between Egypt
and the Mediterranean civilisations.
Trade developed from ritual gifts between tribes. What was the measure
of the value of a gift? As soon as people could form some conception of how
long it took to produce the gifts they got, they would attempt to outdo the
donors in generosity by giving the product of more labour in return.
As trade became more regular, the need naturally arose for a universal
equivalent--something which could readily be exchanged in trade and which
would be accepted generally as a measure of value. At first this need was met
by cattle (the Latin pecunia meaning 'money' is derived from pecus meaning
cattle).
Later this need was fulfilled more conveniently by ingots of metal, in
which there was a burgeoning trade, and which were stamped by the monarchs as a
guarantee of weight.
Ritual gifts would usually be given to the chief as representative of
the tribe. As society grew wealthier, it became worthwhile to be a chief. The
chief's house became the beginnings of a market place in the village.
Metalworking placed a tremendous new power for good or ill in the hands
of men. Metal, particularly copper and bronze, was rare. The first need of
these new societies was defence of the living standards they had built up.
Naturally the tribal chief, as the leading fighting man should be first to
avail himself of the new strategic material.
The consequences of this are to be seen in the legends of the ancient
Greek poet, Homer. He describes the city of Troy besieged by an army of
bronze-armoured Greek military aristocrats. Not mentioned much are the host of
common soldiers, often armed only with flint-tipped spears, who did most of the
fighting and dying. Clearly they are not considered a subject for literature.
The ancient legends of Homer depict a society where primitive communism
had been thrust aside by the evolution of tribal chiefs through a life of war
and plunder into a network of aristocrats and kings. A ruling class now had the
monopoly of effective, armed, might. Thus the development of tribal society
had-produced its own 'grave-diggers', putting an end to classless
equality.
Incidentally, the Germanic sagas arose at an identical stage in the
dissolution of German tribal society. Their "heroic age, produced similar
art forms (epic poetry) and even a similar system of the gods, corresponding to
a similar stage in the development of production as in ancient Greece.
The Bronze Age civilisation described by Homer was swept away by Dorian
invasions, a period equivalent to the west-European Dark Ages. The historical
record dies out for hundreds of years. But the invaders brought something
new--iron.
Iron was potentially more plentiful than bronze. Homer's ruling class
could not have used it to arm the common people, for that would have deprived
them of their military monopoly, the basis of their social power. They fell
before invaders who were still tribesmen.
The invaders' society was not class-divided. So they all used iron
weapons and were invincible for their time. Sometimes mankind has to step back
in order to go forward.
The Asiatic Mode of Production
Civilisation developed differently in different places. So far as we
know, it arose first in the Nile delta of Egypt and in Mesopotamia (in what is
now Iraq), though recent discoveries suggest it may also have developed
independently in India and in South-East Asia at around the same time.
In both Egypt and Mesopotamia the ruling class seems to have sprung
from the elevation of a stratum of priests, rather than chiefs, above the rest
of society. This is because the priests had the leisure to develop a calendar,
allowing them to foretell the coming of the Nile floods, and arithmetic to develop
the centrally planned irrigation works which first produced a massive surplus.
The interest of Egyptian priests in maths and astronomy was thus not
accidental, but rooted in the requirements of production.
Because of the requirements of planned irrigation, as Marx explains:
"The communal conditions for real appropriation through labour, such as
irrigation systems (very important among the Asian peoples), means of
communication, etc., will then appear as the work of the superior entity--the
despotic government which is poised above the small communities."
The Asiatic state which was not accountable in any way to the village
communities, will feel entitled to appropriate the surplus as a tribute. This
tribute is exacted through state ownership of the land: "...the
integrating entity which stands above all these small communities may appear as
the superior or sole proprietor, and the real communities therefore only as
hereditary possessors.''
The villages were largely self-sufficient, rendering tribute to the
Asiatic despotism in order for the "general conditions of production ''
(irrigation, etc.) to be maintained. Handicrafts and agriculture were combined
within each village. The dispersed villages were unable to organise effectively
against their exploitation, so the whole system was very resistant to
change.
This is what Marx and Engels meant when they said that such societies
were "'outside history''. India, for instance, was invaded by one set of
conquerors after another, but none of these political changes reached beneath
the surface.
The Ptolemies, Greek successors of Alexander the Great, who came from a
society where private property in land was at the root of their social system,
left the system as they found it when they conquered Egypt. After all they were
very satisfied with the revenues it provided them.
It was only after thousands of years, when British capitalism conquered
India and strove to introduce private property in land in order to destroy the
unity of native agriculture and handicrafts, and develop the preconditions for
capitalism, that the Asiatic mode of production was finally destroyed. The
result was the decline of the irrigation systems and a series of horrible
famines throughout the nineteenth century.
The Asiatic mode of production saw the first development of class
society, though retaining certain features of primitive communism, such as
collective tilling of the soil. It raised production to a higher level than it
had ever been before, and then stagnated.
Thus, in vast areas of the globe, there arose a form of society
completely different from anything seen in Western Europe. Slavery was known,
but it was not the dominant mode of production. In contrast with western
feudalism, the surplus was extorted by the central state rather than by
landlords.
Once civilisation was established and maintained, it was bound to
radiate its effects all around it, whether through war or trade. Egypt was
always dependent on outside areas for trade, thus stimulating the advance of
civilisation in Crete and thereby giving an enormous impetus to the trading
communities on the Greek coast to develop. Here civilisation found relations of
production--private land-ownership providing an unlimited spur to private
enrichment--which could take humanity forward again.
Ancient Greece: Slavery and
Democracy
Thus, when Greece next enters the historical record, its class
structure is very different from the time of Homer. Trading cities have sprung
up all around the coast. All these cities seem to have been dominated at first
by small ruling classes of landlords who monopolised political rights.
We can speculate that these landlords may have been the original
occupants of the central city zones. As trade developed, the price of their
land would have rocketed, and they would have been able to use their position
to control the marketing of produce. Certainly they used their dominant
position to lend seed to the poorer citizens living on the outskirts, and to
enforce a debt bondage on many. (It is still a matter of scholarly debate
whether the rural people mortgaged their lands or themselves but the form of
exploitation is not important for us here).
As trade developed, the merchant and artisan classes grew in
importance, and campaigned with the poor peasants for political rights. Once
class society had been established, it radiated throughout the main population
centres through warfare and the chance of getting yourself a slice of the
surplus.
All city-states in Greece and Rome were organised around the same
principles. The whole city-state ('polis' in Greek) was unified against every
other city-state, but divided within itself.
It was divided on class lines--and between citizens and slaves.
At first the poor citizens ('plebeians' as they were called in Rome)
were blocked from all political rights. Their struggle was political--to gain a
say in the decision making of the state.
Military survival was also a necessity, and for that the state depended
on the support of the peasantry in the army. The wealthy landlord class needed
the poor citizens to fight for them. That is why a representative of the upper
class, Solon in Athens (the case we know best), actually redistributed the land
to the plebeians in 594 B.C.
In Athens, a predominantly trading centre with a higher concentration
of merchants and artisans, the small men were eventually able to win full
democratic rights. Poor men were paid for public service, and over 5,000
citizens regularly met in the assembly to discuss policy.
The struggle for democracy went through a number of stages. In city
after city the landed oligarchy were first overthrown by tyrants. These men
bore a remarkable resemblance to the later absolutist monarchs who balanced
between the feudal aristocracy and the rising class of merchant capitalists.
Like the absolutists, they used the deadlock in the class struggle to
grab political power for themselves. Like the Tudor monarchs in England, the
political stability they guaranteed allowed the further rise of the moneyed
classes, who from being their sturdiest prop became their staunchest foe, as
they themselves formed aspirations to untrammelled political power. So the era
of the tyrants ended in all the commercial cities of Greece in 'democratic'
revolution.
But Athenian democracy--democracy for the citizens--had as
its foundation the exploitation of a class of non-citizens: slaves who were
without political rights. Athenian democracy was in fact a mechanism for
enforcing the interests of the ruling class over the exploited slave class--and
for defending the interests of the ruling class in war.
The polis was an institution geared up for permanent war. The
power of the city-state was based on independent peasants capable of arming
themselves ('hoplites'). The victory of democracy was inevitable in Athens
after the poor citizens won the naval battle of Salamis against the Persians
for the city. Though too poor to arm themselves, they provided the rowers for
the Athenian navy. A precarious unity of interests was established between rich
and poor citizens through expansion outwards and the conquest of slaves.
By comparison with later Roman slave society the Greek slave mode of
production was relatively "democratic"--as far as the citizens
were concerned. Even poor citizens could own a slave to help around the
farm or workshop, or lease them out to work on slave gangs.
Thus the squeeze was off the poor citizen, for the rich had an
alternative labour supply. The Greek states where democracy did not develop
were mainly inland, where landed wealth was naturally more important than
commercial riches.
Slavery itself was only possible because labour was now capable of
yielding a surplus. That surplus was appropriated by a ruling class who owned the means of
production--in this case the slaves themselves. The state was the state of the
ruling class. The whole structure of society was based upon slave labour--all
the miracles of art, culture and philosophy were only possible because an
exploited class laboured so slaveholders could have leisure.
Slave society had its own dynamic. Its success depended upon the
continual appropriation of more slaves, more unpaid labour.
"Wherever slavery is the main form of production it turns
labour into servile activity, consequently makes it dishonourable for freemen.
Thus the way out of such a mode of production is barred, while on the other
hand slavery is an impediment to more developed production, which urgently
requires its removal. This contradiction spells the doom of all production
based on slavery and of all communities based on it. A solution comes about in
most cases through the forcible subjection of the deteriorating communities by
other, stronger ones (Greece by Macedonia and later Rome). As long as these
themselves have slavery as their foundation there is merely a shifting of the centre
and a repetition of the process on a higher plane until (Rome) finally a people
conquers that replaces slavery by another form of production." (Engels, in
his preparatory writings for Anti-Duhring)
To illustrate this explanation, let us turn to Rome, where slavery
exhausted its potential, and Western European society finally blundered out of
the blind alley it found itself in.
Roman Slavery
Roman society, after the expulsion of its early kings, presents at
first the same aspect as the Greek city states when they were dominated by
landlords (in Rome called "patricians" and organised in the Senate).
Initially they monopolised all political rights. The plebeians waged a
magnificent struggle for a share in power, including the use of the agrarian
general strike, in the form of a 'secession of the tribes'.
But the plebeians were not just poor citizens. They included wealthy
merchants who just wanted to join the patricians in their control of state
power. They headed the plebeian movement and, when they got what they wanted
out of it, deserted it.
One of the definite gains of. these struggles was the abolition of debt
bondage. The gap was filled by the massive expansion of the Roman republic and,
through conquest, the acquisition of hordes of slaves.
The difference with Greece was that the Roman patricians hung on to
power, despite the concessions wrung from them, and monopolised the benefits of
this influx. They linked slave labour to the exploitation of the great farms (latifundia).
In so doing they inevitably undercut the plebeians who, organised in
legions, provided the basis for Roman military greatness.
The dispossessed legionnaires could come back after twenty years of
military service to find their farms choked with weeds. Inevitably they were
ruined and drifted into the town to form a rootless, property less proletariat.
But as the nineteenth century anti-capitalist social critic Sismondi said,
"whereas the Roman proletariat lived at the expense of society, modern
society lives at the expense of the proletariat".
In Rome the Gracchus brothers led a last desperate struggle to save the
independent plebeians. Both were cut down by the bought mob of the patricians.
The crisis of Roman society in the first century B.C., the last century
of the republic, was two-fold in origin.
On the one hand the class struggle had reached a deadlock. The
contradictions spilled over into the army. One general after another cemented
the support of their troops to their own political ambitions by promising
grants of land which the plebeians could not get through their own struggle.
On the other hand, a tiny oligarchy from Rome was now ruling a world
empire through corrupt provincial governors and tax collectors. This form of
rule was quite inadequate. This was brought home in the Social Wars, when
Rome's Italian allies rose in revolt for rights of citizenship. The only way
the Romans could 'win' was by enlisting Italian allies on their side--by
offering rights of citizenship!
So one military man after another stepped into the power vacuum and
progressively enlarged their own power. Finally Caesar Augustus did away with
the republic, relying particularly on the Italian landlords, whom he gave a say
in the running of the state.
Gradually all became citizens, and the privilege was made meaningless,
for all were mere subjects of the Roman Empire. Not for nothing did critics of
the French emperor, Napoleon Bonaparte, call his policies 'Caesarism'. Exactly
the same balancing between classes and groups while building up personal power
characterised both men. Augustus' empire inaugurated a long period of peace.
But for a slave empire, peace is more a menace than war. The supply of slaves
dried up and the price of slaves rose disastrously. Rome had reached its
natural frontiers. It was surrounded by tribes, known as
"barbarians", which it could not conquer.
Decline of the Roman Empire
In this situation the limits of slave production showed themselves. The
slave has no incentive to develop production. He only works under threat of the
whip. Free men for their part despised labour, which they associated with being
an "instrumentum vocale", an 'item of property with a voice',
as the Roman jurists called slaves.
The tragedy of Roman society was that the class struggle was
three-cornered. The poor freemen had their quarrel with the great
slave-holders, but the only pathetic bit of dignity they had to hang on to was
that they were free men, and thus they always made common cause with their
oppressors in the army of the polls in conquering lands for slaves and holding
down slave rebellions.
The slaves for their part lived in a world where slavery was universal,
and so dreamed for the most part of "'enslaving the
slaveholders", not creating a world without slaves.
The burden of keeping together this enormous empire created a huge
swollen state power which guzzled up a great part of the surplus in taxes. The
only self-confident force capable of acting in a centralised way among the
human atoms created by imperial despotism was the army. For a hundred years the
Praetorian Guard made and unmade emperors at their pleasure.
The emperors had one way out of this—to withdraw legions from the
frontier and march against the Praetorian Guard in Rome. All this did was to
reproduce the contradictions on a bigger scale.
When the Emperor Septimus Severus died, he offered this piece of
distilled political wisdom to his sons: "Pay the soldiers. Nothing else
matters." Nobody in the Roman Empire made any secret of the fact that the
state is essentially "armed bodies of men".
As productivity declined, so naturally did trade, and the villas of the
landowners became increasingly self-sufficient, developing in the direction of
the medieval manor (see page 9) which was to replace them. The flight from
money was further boosted by inflation at the end of the third century. The
emperors made sure that they didn't lose out, by demanding taxes in kind.
At the same time they were squeezing the patrician (landlord) class,
now deprived of political power, by forcing them to shell out enormous amounts
on building and circuses. The landlords responded by fleeing to the country and
setting up on their self-sufficient country estates.
Slavery was beginning to die out, not because of humanitarian ideas
supposedly introduced by Christianity, but because it simply did not pay. The
only way slave production could take society forward was through the conquest
of enormous numbers of slaves who could be worked to death in a few years and
replaced.
These conquests had been made possible by the Roman legions of armed
plebeians. But the plebeians had been destroyed by the very success of big
slave-worked farms.
By this time the Romans could only find barbarian mercenaries to man
their armies. Thus Rome was defended from the barbarians by barbarians! Clearly
the empire was living on borrowed time.
Slavery was still important, particularly in domestic service to the
rich, but it gradually ceased to be the dominant mode of production. As
production and trade shrank, it became clear to the landlords that it was
pointless feeding men to work on the fields all the year round when, because of
the natural rhythms of agricultural work, they were idle half the time. Much
better to get them to fend for themselves in periods of slack!
Former slaves were rented plots of land from which they had to pay a
regular part of their produce to the landlord as well as wrench a subsistence
for their family. The state also derived most of its revenue from a land tax
which pressed on the peasantry.
In time, because of the natural tendency for peasants to get into debt
in times of bad harvest, they were bound to the soil in a serf-like condition.
This is called the period of the "colonate".
Eventually the Western Empire was overthrown, not because the
barbarians had become more aggressive and threatening, but because of the inner
rottenness of the empire. We have seen that the productive forces were already
in decline; and in the colonate some of the tendencies, that were to come to
fruition under feudalism, were in the process of coming into existence.
The Transition to Feudalism
The new society created after the Germanic (barbarian) invasions of
Western Europe was a synthesis of declining Roman civilisation and German
tribal society in the process of evolving into class society.
Like the Dorian invasion of early Greek civilisation it seemed a step
back. The decline in production affected every area of social life. Such
chronicles of the Dark Ages as survived (like Gregory of Tours' History
of the Franks) show a childlike credulity in all kinds of ridiculous
miracles--an attitude which would have been laughed to scorn by a Roman
patrician historian.
All the achievements of art and culture only survived in suspended
animation in the institutions of the church. But the barbarians also brought
new ideas and a possibility of moving forward once again. To take just one
example, the Germans had developed a heavy plough which turned over a furrow
rather than just scratching at the surface, and so increased grain yields.
What had been happening among the German tribes in the meantime? The
Romans had maintained themselves for an amazing period of time by 'dividing in
order to rule'. They didn't just divide tribe against tribe, but consciously
developed trade of luxuries to rear a privileged elite among the tribes who
were bought off, and so divided each tribe against itself.
As early as the first century A.D., Tacitus, after describing the
democratic constitution of most of the tribes, moves on to the Suiones, a sea
trading people:
"Wealth, too, is held in high honour; and so a single monarch
rules with no restrictions on his power and with an unquestioned claim to
obedience. Arms are not, as in the rest of Germany, allowed to all and sundry,
but are kept in charge of a custodian who in fact is a slave...idle crowds of
armed men easily get into mischief."
Since tribal society had no state, there was no possibility of
preventing the young men from going out on raiding parties. We all know from
cowboy films- the problems the old chief of the Apaches has in explaining this
principle to the Colonel of the Seventh Cavalry. But whereas the Indian
resistance to capitalist conquest was doomed, raiding parties into the
declining Roman Empire could do very well for themselves.
Retinues built up around the boldest young men. These armed retinues
were thus dependent on an individual and not on the will of the tribe. They
were attached to their leader by gifts of booty. They were the beginning of the
end for tribal society, for bit by bit they became a permanent armed
aristocracy, and elevated their leader to king.
This military aristocracy expropriated the Roman landlords or merged
with them as they entered the territory of the Roman Empire.
It is not the purpose of this pamphlet to trace all the detailed shifts
West European society went through in the next few centuries. But it is
instructive to look at the most serious attempt to replace the lost lustre of
the centralised Roman Empire, the Frankish empire of Charlemagne, and what
happened to it.
Charlemagne conquered huge areas of Europe and set up provinces
governed by counts. To provide food for the armies carrying out his conquests,
the formerly free Frankish peasantry ('Frank', means free) were increasingly
reduced to serf status.
These endeavours were greater than the productive resources of society
could bear. Because productivity was low, communications were primitive. Under
Charlemagne's successors the empire imploded, invaded by Normans, Vikings, and
Saracens, and seemed on the point of collapse.
The local magnates seized their opportunity, setting up castles
everywhere and becoming undisputed lords of the local villages, in return for
defence of the land.
Charlemagne's successors had to accept the situation, granting land
instead of gifts and accommodation to their men at arms, and demanding
acknowledgement of sovereignty and military service in return. It was a measure
of the stage society was at that land was the main form of
wealth--command over land gave access to the privileges of the surplus.
Feudal Society
Feudal society thus emerged in the form of a pyramid of military
obligations to those above in exchange for command of the land to those below.
The whole structure relied on the unpaid labour of the peasants working
on the lords' land. Unlike slaves, they were not the property of the lord.
Feudalism developed untidily. Some in the village were in possession of very
little land and either existed still as slaves or as household servants working
on the lord's land. Freer peasants had land to till and had to pay a rent in
kind. Others had an intermediate status, working small plots to gain their own
subsistence and forced to pay labour services the rest of the time, on the
lord's land.
Exploitation under feudalism is clear and unveiled. The peasants pay
services in money, labour or produce to the lords. Everyone can see what is
going on. If the lord is in a position to force the peasant to work four days
instead of three on his land, then it is clear to both parties that the rate of
exploitation has been increased.
Under slavery, on the contrary, even the part of the working week which
the slave has to work to gain his own subsistence seems to be unpaid. He
therefore seems to work for nothing. Under capitalism, the wageworker is paid a
sum of money which is presented as being the value of his labour. All labour
seems to be paid.
In all three systems the producer is exploited: but the particular form
of exploitation ultimately determined the whole structure of society.
Under feudalism the 'bodies of armed men' which comprised the state
were mainly drawn from the ruling class, who had a monopoly of armed might. So
political and economic power were in the same hands.
Justice in the village was largely in the hands of the lords' manorial
courts. The feudal lord and his men-at-arms were police, judge, and
executioners all rolled into one.
Looking back, we tend to regard feudalism as a static system. Compared
to capitalism it undoubtedly was. But substantial advances were made under the
stabilisation that feudalism provided.
For instance, the population of England probably doubled between 1066
and the fourteenth century--a mark of the advances in production. Large areas
of forest and uncultivated land were put under plough for the first time. Huge
regions of Eastern Europe were colonised by feudalism.
Feudalism provided a limited incentive for the producer to expand
production for his own advantage. Sometimes the lord took the lead in
developing agriculture or colonisation, sometimes the peasants. This depended
on the class struggle. The tendency was for the lord to try to reduce the
peasants' plots to a minimum, encroach on the common lands, and impose serf
status. The peasants, on the other hand, were interested in reducing feudal
dues to a minimum rent.
Innovations such as water and windmills were introduced under the new
system. The lord would attempt to appropriate all the benefits of this advance
by charging exorbitant fees for time use of his mill.
On the continent of Europe in the later middle ages, these 'banalities'
were the main form of feudal revenue. Whether the incentive to produce more
came from the lord's desire for more revenue for luxuries, or from the ambition
of the peasants to set themselves up in business as independent farmers,
production crept up.
But feudalism, like slavery before it imposed limits on the development
of productivity. From generation to generation agricultural productivity was
largely stagnant. The easiest way for the feudal lords to gain more wealth was
to exploit more people. There was therefore a perpetual impulse to warfare, the
net effect of which was to waste and destroy the productive forces.
Medieval Towns
Like previous forms of class society, feudalism in its development
produced the germs of a new society in the towns.
Roman towns had been much bigger and more impressive than the towns of
the feudal Middle Ages, but they did not have the same possibilities for
development. Roman cities started out as collections of landlords with an
attendant trade in luxuries, and as administrative centres which fleeced the
surrounding countryside. Medieval cities, on the other hand, were centres of
trade and handicrafts.
As productivity developed, trade necessarily grew. Artisans, who had
been attached to aristocratic households and monasteries in the dark ages,
gathered together to trade with the rural areas in goods that could be produced
quicker and therefore cheaper, or could only be produced by skilled
specialists.
Whether these towns were originally established by the embryo of a new
commercial class or by progressive feudal lords to exploit the new needs, they
represented a new principle. Unlike the universal relations of dominance and
subservience of feudalism, they were free associations of trading people,
producing what one representative of the feudal lords called that "new and
detestable name", the commune.
Within the towns production and trade was organised in guilds, divided
on craft lines. These attempted to regulate production, price and quality.
After the Black Death (the terrible plague that spread across Europe in
the fourteenth century) had bypassed Poland, the guilds decided to thank the
Lord by celebrating more holy days. What they were actually doing, of course,
was sharing out the work because of the reduction in custom.
The guilds began as bands of equals but, as towns grew in size due to
the constant influx of refugee serfs looking for a better life, guild masters
were able to make it more difficult for journeymen to join their ranks.
At the same time, merchant guilds were able to exploit their position
over the artisan guilds to become an urban elite. Most towns were dominated by
a tiny oligarchy, until a series of revolts by poor craftsmen to gain some say
in the running of the council took place at the end of the Middle Ages.
Because of this natural differentiation produced anew by commodity
production, the oligarchy in time regained their former status. At the same
time all the towns were engaged in battles for a charter of liberties from the
landlord class.
As the productivity of labour grew, so did trade, and production for
the market, commodity production, and a money economy. Increasingly, grain
crops were produced for sale to feed the towns. A stratum of peasants grew rich
at their fellows' expense, and aspired to become land-owning farmers producing
for a market.
In England, though, it was mainly the feudal lords who took the
initiative in reorienting production towards the market. Wool production became
more important, and the lords would strive to grab the common lands and
expropriate the peasantry.
Serfdom had largely died out in England by the end of the fourteenth
century, but bondage to the soil was replaced by short-term leases and an
increasing stream of poor peasants being pushed out altogether and forced into
vagabondage (roaming the land in search of a living).
By the seventeenth century, it was reckoned that up to quarter of the
population was without any means of livelihood other than begging. Progress, as
ever, was achieved at the expense of the common people.
Class Struggle Under Feudalism
Whereas the class struggle between patricians and plebeians was
political, concerned with access to state power, the feudal class struggle was
mainly waged on the economic plane.
A constant, unremitting struggle took place between landlords and
peasants. Occasionally this spilt over into revolutionary strife. The Peasants,
Revolt of 1381 was the most notable such occasion in England.
After the Black Death, the peasants were in a strong position because
of the shortage of labour. The landlords attempted to recoup their losses by
enforcing traditional obligations all the harder. This produced a social
explosion.
It is significant that the vanguard of the revolutionary peasantry was
in the commercial crop areas of the southeast. The development of trade
expanded communications and had the effect of binding people together over
large areas. Though the revolt was unsuccessful in its immediate objectives, it
had the effect of rolling back the predatory ambitions of the feudal lords.
The revolt failed at bottom because the peasantry were a scattered
class divided against themselves. King Richard II urged them to "go back
to their haymaking", and he hit them on their weak point. It was
impossible to maintain the peasantry in a permanent state of mobilisation.
Production had developed to a point where only a minority of the population
could be maintained as fighting men, while the majority had to work on the
land.
This point is illustrated by the Italian peasant revolt, led by Fra
Dolcino at a similar time. Though dressed up in religious ideas, the advanced
sections of the peasantry developed primitive communist aspirations.
Fra Dolcino and his followers retreated to the Italian Alps. They had
to eat and they had to defend themselves. The beginnings of the split in their
ranks between fighters and toilers produced demoralisation and defeat.
In this example we can see how the institutions of feudalism
corresponded to the then existing state of the productive forces. The miseries
of the past have been a necessary travail for mankind.
From Feudalism to Capitalism
Marx called the process of the dissolution of feudalism and emergence
of capitalism "primitive accumulation''. This process is one of piling up
of fortunes in money rather than land on the one hand, and the creation of a
property less proletariat on the other. It is the separation of the producers
from the means by which they can maintain themselves.
We have seen that the feudal peasantry was attached to the land. This
guaranteed them a modest subsistence except in times of famine.
Nobody will work for money, with all the insecurity that entails,
unless they have to. That is why the imperialists in Africa introduced money
poll taxes and, in the case of South Africa drove the Africans on to barren
reserves, to force them to provide a supply of wage labour. That is why a
monopoly of land in the hands of private owners is a condition for the
development of capitalism.
The process by which the peasantry was dispossessed in England was
described by Marx in Capital. The dissolution of the monasteries, when
the church owned one-third of all land, produced an immense mass of ex-monastic
paupers. Earlier, the disbandment of the feudal retinues after the Wars of the
Roses produced a ferocious breed of vagabonds.
But the main lever of dispossession was the passing of private Acts of
Parliament through a parliament of landlords, called Acts of Enclosure. This
was simply legalised robbery. It came at a time when the wool trade was expanding,
and the landlords wanted more land in order to graze flocks of sheep. Land
formerly occupied by perhaps five hundred people was decreed to be the squire's
land, and a couple of shepherds took the villagers' place.
Brutal as this process was, it advanced production on the land by doing
away with the old inefficient strip system and laying the basis for rational
agriculture. Later, the advantages of the industrial revolution-modern
machinery could be applied to these big farms.
The other pole of the process of primitive accumulation was the
accumulation of money. The first forms of capital, before industrial capital
transformed production, were merchant capital and money-lending capital.
The 'discovery' of America by Spanish plunderers shifted the axis of
world trade. Huge fortunes were made in the 'New World'.
The Spanish search for gold was accompanied by the most horrible
brutality. Under their rule the numbers of the Indians of San Domingo fell from
a population of a million in 1492 to ten thousand in 1530. In Cuba the native
population fell from 600,000 in 1492 to only 270 households in 1570.
The merchant capitalist powers outdid one another in their cruelty.
Slavery, long thought dead, underwent a renaissance to provide labour for the
mines and plantations to serve the world market.
At the same time, the late middle ages saw the rise of great banking
families, such as the Fuggers, feeding the needs of the mighty for more and
more money. Knights, and princes, feudal revenue could not keep up with the new
luxuries available to them. This was clear evidence that production relations
on the land were a fetter on the development of the productive forces.
The monarchy too felt the need for more money and began to borrow. So
this was the period when every nation began to run up its national debt, which
is still with us today and currently standing in Britain at about £100,000
million (1983).
At the end of the middle ages absolutist monarchs like the Tudors in
England sprang up in most of the West European countries. These monarchies
balanced between the old landed ruling class and the up-and-coming capitalists.
To start with they took society forward by forming strong, stable
nation-states within which trade, and hence capitalism, could develop. They
defended the interests of merchants abroad in wars of conquest for colonies.
Yet, at bottom, they were out for themselves, and could only flourish
because of a deadlock in the class struggle between the capitalists and the
landowners. As capitalism developed further, the rising capitalist class
conceived ambitions for political power to match their growing economic power. Bourgeois
revolutions aimed against the reigning absolute monarchs would become
necessary for capitalism to consolidate its rule.
Developments parallel to those in agriculture took place in handicraft
(manufacturing) production. We have seen how the guilds reflected production
relations which originally institutionalised an advance in production.
Later they became a barrier, as capitalists outside the guilds addressed
themselves to mobilising wage labour to produce for the ever-increasing
markets.
The guilds worked on the principle of limiting production to keep up
prices, and used their traditional privileges to resist inroads. Merchant
capitalists moved in to lap up the surplus labour of peasant households
half-employed on tiny plots of land. They began to 'put out' weaving to these
households.
The peasantry became more and more dependent on their weaving income.
The merchants were able to move from just supplying raw materials and supplying
sales outlets, to possession of the peasants, looms and even their cottages.
Through their control over outlets they held the whip hand.
This was another important process whereby the feudal peasantry was
reduced to proletarian status.
Throughout the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, handicraft
workshops were set up. It was found that the job could be broken down into
simple processes. Adam Smith begins his 'Wealth of Nations' by
explaining the division of labour in making pins, through which an enormous
amount of pins could be cheaply produced compared with the old skilled
processes.
More than that, the breaking down of the job into simple repetitive
tasks provided the possibility of replacing manual labour with machines.
Starting by taking production as it found it, capitalism was beginning to
revolutionise the instruments of production.
Capitalism could not move straight into domination of the world economy
without hindrance. The newly awakened productive forces were in revolt at the
old relations of production. These had to be overcome and new production
relations installed which corresponded to the stage of development of the
productive forces.
This was the task of the bourgeois revolutions. The English Revolution
of the 1640s, the American Revolution of 1776, and the French Revolution of
1789-94 were the decisive struggles which laid the foundations for the
domination of capitalism on a world scale.
What precisely were the tasks of these bourgeois revolutions?
Though feudalism was no longer dominant, the landed interest remained a
fetter on commodity production.
Though in England the land-owning gentry switched to production for the
market, in France up till 1789 the aristocracy guzzled a large part of the surplus
in rents, and used their privileged position to impose all kinds of tolls on
the free movement of goods.
This raised prices for everyone and enabled the bourgeoisie, in
opposing the aristocracy, to claim to represent the interests of the nation as
a whole. Up till the storming of the Bastille by the Parisian masses in 1789,
for instance, food-entering Paris was subject to a toll as a feudal privilege.
France was the classic country of the bourgeois revolution, where the
old aristocracy was completely swept aside. The peasantry, increasingly
producing for a market, had a tendency after the bourgeois revolution of 1789
to become divided into an aspiring capitalist class and a property less class
of rural wage labourers.
Capitalism also had the task of setting up centralised national
economies as an envelope within which the new mode of production could develop.
Germany as late as the nineteenth century showed the necessity for
capitalist production to have a stable nation-state. Germany was still divided into
thirty-six statelets on the eve of the 1848 revolution, each originally having
its own currency, its own system of tolls and tariffs, its own weights, land
measures and local communications.
Clearly this confusion of small states provided an almost impenetrable
barrier to the development of large scale, all-German industry and trade. The
failure of the German bourgeoisie to carry through "their own"
revolution, because of their fear of the new working class behind them, led to
these tasks being carried out under the hegemony of the Prussian junkers (landlords)
around Bismarck—who saw the need to build a modern capitalist nation.
In Britain and France, on the other hand, national unification had
already been substantially carried out by the absolutist monarchies as one of
the progressive tasks of developing the framework of capitalist development.
Nor was the old aristocracy the only section to resist progress. A
section of the capitalists, who had originally taken society forward, became
increasingly reactionary. Rich merchants used their influence on the kings to
gain monopolies in trade. They used their privileges to raise the price of
commodities.
These reactionary capitalists were opposed by the smaller merchants,
who were forced to fight for free trade, and by the urban masses. Likewise, big
moneylenders made their money by lending to the crown, and thus were dependent
on the monarchy.
The capitalist class as a whole was now strong enough to bid for
political power, which it needed to complete its revolution. The absolutist
monarchies, from being a shield to defend the expansion of trade, had become an
obstacle. They had to be done away with; and the masses of artisans and yeomen
were mobilised to do the job for the capitalist class.
Capitalism
Capitalists measure their wealth not in land or slaves, but in money.
The money fortunes found their way into production in the industrial
revolution, a period as significant for mankind as the agricultural revolution
thousands of years earlier.
Capitalism is a system of exploitation like feudalism or
slavery. Its distinctive feature is that rather than just consuming the
surplus, the capitalists are forced by the nature of their system to plough the
bulk of it back into production.
Capitalism thus achieves a dynamic unheard of in earlier epochs.
Instead of just exploiting more people, as feudal lords strove to do through
never-ending wars, capitalism exploits people more--it develops the
productivity of labour.
In so doing it provides the possibility of a society of abundance, and so for doing away altogether with the division between exploiter and exploited. It provides, in other words, the possibility of a higher
stage of society than capitalism itself.
Capitalism bases itself on the monopoly of the means of production in the hands of the ruling capitalist class. The vast majority of people are cut
off from the means of life unless they work on terms dictated by the capitalist
class.
Formally, wageworkers seem to be paid for the work they do. In reality
they are exploited as much as the feudal serf or the slave.
Under capitalism, labour-power (the capacity of the worker to labour)
is a commodity like any other, in that it is bought and sold on the market. It
is sold by its owner, the worker, and bought by the owner of money, the
capitalist.
But labour-power is different from other commodities in this respect:
it has the unique property of being able to create value. This is its
usefulness to the capitalist, this is why the capitalist buys labour-power
(employs workers).
As labour-power is consumed in production (as workers are put to work)
value is created far in excess of what the capitalist has paid (as wages) for
the labour-power. This is the source of the capitalist's profit.
If labour-power is to be available in the market place, so that the
capitalist can buy it, labour-power must be produced. "Given the
individual," Marx wrote, "the production of labour-power consists in
his reproduction of himself, or his maintenance''. Marx adds immediately that
this maintenance contains "a historical and moral element"--i.e.,
what a working-class family require for their maintenance, and for the raising
of children as a new generation of wageworkers, will depend on standards of
living which have been established through struggle as acceptable to the
working class in that society.
The essence of capitalist exploitation is this: The worker is paid wages not for his/her labour but for his/her labour-power—his/her keep. The difference is taken by the capitalist.
Thus the worker's daily work is divided into "necessary labour" and "surplus labour''. The worker performs "necessary labour'' during that part of the day spent in producing value which, when sold, will cover the cost of the wages. The worker performs "surplus labour'' during the remainder of the working day, producing value which, when sold, will cover the rent, interest and profit which goes to the capitalist class.
Capitalism at first strove to increase the rate of exploitation through enforcing repeated increases in the working day (the workers were usually paid by the day, however many hours they worked). The capitalists were able to get away with this because of the almost endless reserve army of labour created by the destruction of petty production in town and country, and the driving of hordes of starving poor into the cities.
This meant that workers had to work on almost any terms dictated by the
bosses. But the capitalist system was in danger of killing the goose that laid
the golden egg. Surveys undertaken in Britain during the 1850s showed a
stunted, prematurely enfeebled race of workers unfit for military service.
In the nineteenth century, British workers began the struggle for the
legal limitation of the working day, what Marx called "the first victory
for the political economy of the working class". We must note, though,
that, like later reforms such as the National Health Service--the Ten Hours Act
was also in the long-term interests of the ruling class because it maintained a
labour supply in fit condition.
Nevertheless, because of the shortsighted greed of capitalists, these
reforms were only enforced through struggle in the teeth of ruling-class
opposition.
Thus, thwarted from indefinitely increasing the rate of surplus-value through what Marx called the extraction of absolute surplus value (e.g., by increasing the working day), the capitalists were forced to move to increasing the rate of exploitation through the extraction of relative surplus-value.
This means, instead of getting more hours of labour out of the workers,
they had to raise the productivity of the workers' labour--to get more output
from the same hours of work.
The more productive labour is, the less of the working day needs to be
devoted to producing the value of the necessities of life for the workers
(their wages), and the more time can be devoted to producing surplus for the
capitalist.
The motor of capitalism is competition. Each capitalist has to undercut his competitors if he is to survive. The best way to sell cheaper is to produce cheaper. Since labour-time is the measure of value, that means producing with less labour-time.
Mechanising is the main means of continually raising the productivity of labour. Perhaps the best example of the process is the one supplied by Marx—the case of the handloom weavers.
The invention of the spinning jenny, and the mass-production of cheaper
yarn, led to the mechanisation of cloth making. Weaving, up to then, had still
been a handicraft process. As demand for weavers expanded in the early years of
the industrial revolution, the hand-loom weavers were able to bid up their
wages and become a regular 'aristocracy of labour'. For capitalism they
represented an obstacle to cheap production. Inevitably, as a result, the power
loom was invented, for capitalist necessity is the mother and father of
invention.
It would be quite clear to any casual observer that the power loom took
much less labour-time to produce an equivalent amount of woven cloth.
In vain did the handloom weavers bid the price of their product down.
In no way could they compete with the power loom.
At their peak there had been a quarter of a million handloom weavers.
Over a generation they were wiped out with thousands actually dying of
starvation. A much smaller number were able to get jobs, at lower rates of pay,
supervising the power looms.
That has ever been the way with capitalist progress. But in this way
capitalism has developed the fantastic productive powers of modern industry.
Capitalism also develops a form of the state appropriate to its own rule. Different forms of state can exist under capitalism, each corresponding to a different stage in the development of the class struggle--from parliamentary democracy to fascism and Bonapartist military-police dictatorships of the most variegated kinds.
All these forms of state have one thing in common--in the last analysis
they defend private property in the means of production, and therefore the rule
of capital.
Marx and Engels often emphasised that democracy is the ideal form of
capitalist class rule, first because it enables the capitalists to sort out
their differences; and secondly because it gives the working-class parties a
semblance of a say of running society. Changes necessary for the continued
existence of the system can thus more easily be made.
At the same time bourgeois democracy provides the most favourable
ground for the workers to organise to overthrow their exploiters.
Capitalism has required, as a precondition of its existence, a new class of property less toilers. Throughout its development capitalism has created a bigger and bigger pool of wageworkers.
Even since the Second World War, millions of small farmers have been driven from the land in countries such as France, Italy and Japan. This has been a progressive step in so far as it tears these people away from the isolation and backwardness of rural life, and in so far as it represents a raising of the productivity of labour, so that less people are needed to grow food and more can set their hands to producing other things.
But, at the same time, capitalism has no regard for the interests of
people, and relentlessly searches out surplus value at any cost to the masses.
The Capitalist World Market
As we have seen, though it has created misery for the masses, capitalism has been a dynamic system. Its aim and impulse is more and more surplus value.
Thus industrial capitalism strives to conquer the world. Merchant capital had contented itself with exacting tribute from the existing modes of production in other countries; industrial capital, in the empires it created after the industrial revolution, flooded these countries with cheap manufactured goods.
These goods necessarily destroyed the existing system of handicrafts, which was united with agriculture in the villages.
Existing societies were forcibly broken up. Moreover agriculture was increasingly switched towards the requirements of the world market. Capitalism was beginning to create a world after its own image.
This process was brought to its highest stage in the imperialist phase of capitalist development.
The different phases through which capitalist countries entered into relations with pre-capitalist nations--and in exploiting them, drew them into the orbit of capitalism, can be seen clearly in the case of India.
In the first instance India was colonised not by the British government
but by the East India Company, an association of merchants. They made fortunes
for themselves by monopolising Anglo-Indian trade, buying cheap and selling
dear. They also strove to grab the internal trade of India, and under their
greedy control the price of grain skyrocketed during famines--beyond the reach
of the needy.
The period of domination of the East India Company corresponded to the
requirements of primitive accumulation in Britain. Money fortunes were made by
the merchant adventurers through unequal exchange. After the Battle of Plassey,
which gave Britain sway over the entire Indian subcontinent, the Bank of
England printed £10 and £15 notes for the first time. The conservative historian,
Burke, estimated that plunder from India between 1757 and 1780 amounted to £40
million, a huge figure for that time.
British capitalism was not always an advocate of international free
trade. That came later, when Britain had a monopoly of large-scale capitalist
production. In fact, Indian textiles imported into Britain had duties of 70% to
80% imposed on them right up to about 1830.
It was only when the Lancashire machine textile industry had built up
an unassailable position that restrictions were lifted because they were no
longer necessary. The Indian market was then flooded with cheap cotton goods,
and its own textile producers ruined.
The fate of Indian society was now bound up with the development of
competitive capitalism. Incidentally, British capitalism did not hesitate to
resort to the most barbarous methods of imposing their exports upon the
Indians. For instance, the hands of weavers in Dacca were cut off! Terrible
famine stalked the area, and the whole region became partly overgrown with jungle.
In 1850 India absorbed one quarter of Lancashire textiles.
After the Indian Mutiny, which began in 1857, the British rulers saw the need to build up a network of railways, to allow rapid troop movements, in order to keep the population pinned down. This marked the beginning of the third phase of the exploitation of India. Export of capital rather than of goods became the predominant feature.
Imperialism
This development was the result of the growth of monopoly capitalism in the metropolitan countries, involving the fusion of finance with manufacturing capital—the epoch of imperialism, which was analysed by Lenin. National markets became too small for the giant monopolies as they swallowed up their weaker competitors, expanded production to new heights, and looked for new and profitable areas for investment.
In the case of India, this process really got going at the end of the
nineteenth century when capital was exported from Britain to build up a modern
Indian-based textile industry, mainly under British ownership.
"One capitalist kills many", as Marx says. Capitalism
destroys not only petty production, but also continually bankrupts the weakest
of its own brethren and jettisons them into the ranks of the property less.
This is a two-sided process--progressive in its objective economic
content, by piling up enormous productive resources for the potential benefit
of mankind, but, under capitalism, concentrating colossal power in
the hands of a tiny handful of rich magnates.
At the end of the nineteenth century we saw the development of monopoly
out of competition itself.
The banking system, Marx wrote, "places all the available and even
potential capital of society that is not already actively employed at the
disposal of the industrial and commercial capitalists, so that neither the
lenders nor users of this capital are its real owners or producers. It thus
does away with the private character of capital and thus contains in itself,
but only in itself, the abolition of capital itself... Finally there is no doubt
that the credit system will serve as a powerful lever during the transition
from the capitalist mode of production to the mode of production of associated
labour, but only as one element in connection with other great organic
revolutions of the mode of production itself."
Capitalism continually requires infusions of money capital in order for
profit-making to continue uninterruptedly. Once a stock of commodities has been
produced, a single capitalist would either have to wait till he had sold them
before he once again had money in his pocket to restart production; or he would
have to keep stocks of money-capital idle much of the time as a reserve for
investment when needed; he would have to continually pay money into a fund to
renew stocks of fixed capital which might be idle for ten or twenty years.
In reality, a stratum of capitalist hangers-on develop, not prepared to
invest directly in production, but quite prepared to lend their money in order
to cut themselves a slice of the pie of surplus-value. So there is a tendency
for competition to generate unused reserves of money capital. These reserves
are collected in a few rich hands— concentrations of finance capital.
Finance capital initially provided a stimulus to the capitalist system
by gathering and siphoning money-capital into production. It did so, of course,
only to cream off an increasing proportion of the surplus value for itself.
As Marx pointed out, finance capital also concentrates tremendous
economic power in its own hands, and effectively integrates the individual
manufacturing capitalist into the requirements of capitalist production as a
whole through allocation and withdrawal of credits.
Imperialism is the epoch in which finance capital has fused with
monopoly capital involved in production.
Under imperialism, while competition between capitalists within the
boundaries of the nation-state has not been completely done away with, conflict
has spilt over into the international arena.
The big monopolies and the banks exported capital rather than just
commodities. A massive programme of railway building was undertaken in every
continent and clime. Loans were floated for the most far-flung places. A
systematic search was undertaken for every kind of raw material and mineral
resource.
Conflicts now began between national capital blocs. The struggle was
for nothing less than mastery of the world. Wars unparalleled in ferocity in
the history of mankind broke out for colonies and a redivision of imperial
spoils.
The First World War indicated that capitalism, like previous forms of
class society, had ceased to be progressive. Instead of taking production
forward, there was mass destruction and mass murder.
But at the same time, a new society was developing within the old. The
Russian revolution served notice that the rule of the working class was at
hand.
Revolutionary Role of the Working
Class
The working class is unlike any other exploited class in history. We have seen how the three-sided class struggle within slave society necessarily led to the "common ruin of the contending classes". We have seen how the feudal peasantry were for hundreds of years incapable of formulating a coherent revolutionary alternative to the system that exploited them.
This failure had not been accidental. The peasantry is an isolated class, scattered over the countryside and finding it very difficult to combine. But their problem is not just geographical, it is at bottom social. For as Marx put it, the peasantry is a class only in one sense:
"in so far as millions of families live under economic conditions of existence that separate their mode of life, their interests and their culture from those of the other classes, and put them in hostile opposition to the latter, they form a class. In so far as...the identity of their interests begets no community, no national bond and no political organisation among them, they do not form a class."
For the peasantry are smallholders—a class divided against itself. They
are like potatoes in a sack—destined for the chipping machine under capitalist
progress.
The working class, on the other hand, is concentrated in great masses
by the very nature of factory production. Unlike the peasantry, their only
strength lies in collective action. Through collective exploitation, the
working class are trained and educated by capitalism itself to act as the
system's gravediggers.
Capitalist Crisis
Nor is the modern working class left to vegetate at a modest but constant standard of living. Insecurity is a condition of their existence.
Capitalism has produced many wonders inconceivable hitherto. It has also produced social disasters inconceivable under previous forms of society—crises taking the form of overproduction.
In pre-capitalist societies, the subsistence of the toilers was only interrupted by famine—physical shortage of necessities. Primitive people's minds may well have been clogged with all sorts of superstition, but the spectacle of people starving, while sitting idly in front of the tools necessary to make the things they need, is a unique product of our society.
Capitalism is social production. It is social in two ways. Firstly, it ties the whole world up into one economic unit through the world market, a worldwide division of labour. Everybody is dependent on everyone else for the things they need.
Secondly it introduces large-scale production only workable by collective labour.
Yet, at the same time, the system runs on private appropriation and private profit. It is anarchic—nobody knows how much of any commodity is needed at any time. The capitalist plans production within his own factory, but social production as a whole is unplanned.
Marx wrote: "Capitalist production seeks continually to overcome
these immanent barriers but overcomes them only by means which again place the
barriers in its way and on a more formidable scale. The real barrier of
capitalist production is capital itself". (Capital Vol. 3)
"The same bourgeois mind which praises division of labour in the
workshop, life-long annexation of the labourer to a partial operation and his
complete subjection to capital, as being an organisation of labour that
increases its productiveness—that same bourgeois mind denounces with equal
vigour every conscious attempt to socially control and regulate the process of
production, as an inroad upon such sacred things as the rights of property,
freedom and unrestricted play for the bent of the individual capitalist. It is
very characteristic that the enthusiastic apologists of the factory system have
nothing more damning to urge against a general organisation of the labour of
society than that it would turn all society into one immense factory". (Capital
Vol. l)
How is 'overproduction' possible? The reason people can't just walk
into the factories, and start producing the things they want, is because they
don't own those factories: and the state defends the property interests of the
ruling class.
The ruling class, for their part, produce only to make profit. No profit, no jobs.
Every worker laid off by one capitalist means one less consumer for another capitalist's goods. So crisis, triggered off in any one major sector of the economy, can radiate throughout the system.
Crises of mass unemployment are as much a creation of capitalism as Coca Cola.
The laws of capitalism work, "despite anarchy, in and through anarchy". Each capitalist is oblivious to the actual requirements of society for pig iron or knicker-elastic at any time. They produce what they hope will make the maximum profit, whether pig iron or knicker-elastic. They organise production within their factory; but anarchy reigns in production as a whole.
The possibility of crisis is inherent in such a system. All that socialists want to do is plan production in society at large in the same meticulous way the capitalists do within each separate factory.
The worker, unlike the exploited classes in pre-capitalist society, is
a free person—free in that he is not subject to "relations of personal dependence" and can work for any boss he likes, and free from any attachment to the means of subsistence. But the workers' expectations and feelings of security are continually shattered by plagues of mass unemployment.
Crisis poses over and over again before the working class the need to change society. Capitalism will never collapse of its own accord. It has to be
overthrown.
It is a caricature of Marxism to suggest that the revolution will be made automatically by workers made destitute by the workings of the system. It will be overthrown by a conscious and determined class, not just by a desperate class.
What is true is that the perpetual insecurity of existence under
capitalism will produce a questioning in the minds of workers. Just as we have
to understand nature in order to master it, so workers will have to understand
the nature of their enemy before they can overthrow it.
That is why we are producing this pamphlet.
We have outlined the progress of mankind from primitive communism to
capitalism. An objective look at the record shows also the world we have lost.
Chief Sitting Bull, an outstanding defender of Native American tribal society,
ended up miserably as a kind of freak in Buffalo Bill's Wild West Show. As he
toured the Western capitals he was astounded at the wealth—but also at the
poverty. He said, "The white man (by which he meant the capitalist system)
knows how to produce wealth, not how to distribute it".
Yet the possibility now exists for a society where enough can be produced for each to take according to their need. The possibilities posed before mankind by science and new technology were foreseen by Marx over 120 years ago. In one of his notebooks he wrote:
"No longer does the worker insert a modified natural thing as middle link between the object and himself; rather he inserts the process of nature, transformed into an industrial process, as a means between himself and unorganic nature mastering it. In this transformation it is...the development of the social individual which appears as the great foundation stone of production and of wealth. The theft of alien labour-time, on which the present is based, appears a miserable foundation in face of this new one, created by large-scale industry itself...
"The surplus labour of the mass has ceased to be the condition for the development of general wealth, just as the non-labour of the few, for the development of the human head... The free development of individuals and hence...the general reduction of the necessary labour of society to a minimum, which then corresponds to the artistic, scientific, etc., development of the
individuals in the time set free, and with the means created, for all of them." (Grundrisse)
The !Kung people in the Kalahari live lives of material want and intellectual backwardness by our standards, but they know better than to make
labour for others the driving force of their society. In consequence they work a week of between 12 and 19 hours!
Now mankind has the resources and technical means to reach a society of abundance. The working class, organised and conscious, can overthrow capitalism and create such a society - a society where people can plan what they need and want, produce it, and then spend the rest of the time enjoying it. It's as simple as that.
Historical Materialism was written for the Journal of the Marxist Workers' Tendency of the ANC, Inqaba ya basebenzi,as a supplement to the edition of November 1983.
To read further documents produced by the CWI, pleae return to the Documents section.