1. Modelling Core Inflation
As detailed in the introduction, the core inflation term will be based upon the backward-looking theory. The weighted average will be over the previous two years, with up to eight quarters, as determined econometrically, and of the general form:
p* = a + St=1L pt-L
where p is inflation, p* represents core inflation, a is a constant and L is the lag length, such that 1<L<8.
The model chosen has six lags, therefore one and a half years, representing, in one way, the longevity of inflation in people's expectations.
p* = 0.426 + 1.234pt-1 - 0.082pt-2 - 0.206pt-3 - 0.330pt-4 + 0.498pt-5 - 0.166pt-6 (2)
Clearly the inconsistency of the signs of each regressor is puzzling. One would expect that recent inflation would cause current inflation and hence a positive sign. The first lag has a strong effect, whereby last quarter's inflation has an effect on current inflation greater than its actual value, such that inflation of 5% in period 1 would have a value of just over 6%12 in period 2. One interpretation of this is that, as well as the monetary effect, people fear inflation as they see it eroding their wealth and so there is a psychological effect. Therefore, when making their expectations for the next quarter, consumers will anticipate even higher inflation.
As well as the signs, the varying coefficients are unexpected, as there is no trend for
past values to have significantly less effect. In fact, the coefficients of the lagged
periods two, three and six could justifiably be set to zero
These lag lengths constrain all variables except incomes policy which can range from
four to twelve lags. If more than one model satisfies both economic reasoning and
econometric tests, I will select the most appropriate using the "general to simple"
approach, discussed earlier.
Having decided this, the functional form for inflation can be expressed as:
pt = a + pt* + Si=01 bix1t-i + Si=04 bix2t-i + Si=0L bix3t-i, where L=4,8,12.
Having worked through the regression, the most suitable model was found to have
four lags on the incomes policy. This comes as somewhat of a relief, as it is the most
parsimonious model and hence easier to manipulate and discuss. Consequently, we
have:
pt = -0.096080 + 0.99517pt* + 0.039207x1t + 0.94839x1t-1 -
0.000156x2t + 0.000273x2t-1 - 0.000022x2t-2 + 0.00003254x2t-3 -
0.000027x2t-4 + 0.38992x3t - 0.41723x3t-1 -0.9017x3t-2 - 0.18939x3t-3
+ 1.4065x3t-4 (3)
Before commenting on this model, it is worth considering how one would expect the
variables to behave. Starting with core inflation, I would anticipate a positive sign,
given that consumers use past information. The higher the value of p*, the more
emphasis is placed on past inflation when calculating expectations for future levels.
The relative price of imports variable should also have a positive sign for two reasons.
Firstly, an increase in the relative import price will affect firms who import factors of
production and increase costs. The second way is more direct. If consumer goods are
amongst those imports which increase in price, the selling price in Britain will be
higher. However, it is worth noting that, if the relative price does increase, consumers
may switch to domestically produced goods, which would reduce the price effect
somewhat, although not entirely as the domestic goods must have been more
expensive, else they would already have been consumed. The higher the value of the
coefficients, the greater the effect of the price rise on inflation.
I would also expect a positive sign on the demand shocks variable, as an increase in
aggregate demand (AD) leads to a rise in prices, ceteris parabus. The actual value of
the coefficients, also from Keynesian theory, depends on where the aggregate supply
(AS) curve lies. Figure 2 shows the standard Keynes AS curve and three possible AD
curves:
If the coefficients are close to zero it implies AD1 on the diagram, with the economy
having spare resources. In this case, rising AD would have a very small effect on
prices. As the coefficients increase in value, we move along the AS curve to AD2 and
as resources start running short we approach AD3, which is full employment and any
demand increase is purely inflationary.
Finally, the troublesome variable of incomes policy. Since this is a policy designed to
prevent inflation, it should have a negative sign. The closer the coefficients are to -1,
the more successful the policy has been.
Now, compare the actual results to the theory. The core inflation term is positive, as
anticipated, and is close to one, reinforcing the theory that consumers are backward-
looking and that they consider past inflation when making their predictions about
future conditions. This is a key consideration for government planners, as it means
that, when high inflation occurs, people become pessimistic and expect it to continue.
In fact, the theory implies that inflation will continue increasing.
The relative price of imports have a positive sign on both terms, which is correct, and
the lagged term is significant, although the present term's effect is small. This is
consistent with my belief that the effect on inflation takes time to filter through and,
consequently, we should consider the previous quarter's situation more than the
current quarter.
Surprisingly, demand shocks are insignificant and also have mixed signs, in contrast
to the theory. A minus sign, as appears on the current period and second and fourth
lag, implies that increasing aggregate demand leads to lower inflation, which is
against all theory. However, the small coefficients suggest that changes in AD have
little effect on inflation. With the coefficient of core inflation being approximately
one, the small demand shock coefficients suggests the economy is at the natural rate
of unemployment.
The incomes policy term also has mixed signs. Considering first the size of the
coefficient, the policy certainly has a significant effect on inflation. However, there is
no pattern to the absolute value of the coefficients to suggest that the effect
diminishes or increases over time. Returning to the sign of the coefficients, whilst
being against what I expected, it is not altogether inconceivable that this could be the
case. Considering the implication, incomes policy has caused higher inflation. This
could happen if the policy was incorrectly used and the wrong outcome was achieved
or could mean that, when the policy is not in effect, wages, for example, are
increasing to compensate for the anticipated incomes policy.
3. Alternative Measure of Demand Shock
Given the insignificant values for GDP deviation as the demand shock, it is prudent to
consider another measure, namely my alternative of capacity utilisation. Maintaining
the same notation as previously, the model generated is with only the current level of
capacity utilisation.
pt = -2.2326 + 1.0072pt* -0.11058x1t + 0.60565x1t-1 + 0.066728x2t -
0.22091x3t + 0.23489x3t-1 - 1.5216x3t-2 - 0.87280x3t-3 + 2.6447x3t-4
(4)
Again the core inflation term has a coefficient of approximately one and there is a
mixture of signs on the incomes policy lags. However, the effect of import prices in
the current period appears incorrect, as the sign is now negative. Considering the
significance of the demand shock proxy, we see a larger coefficient than with GDP
deviations but still small compared to other variables, in some ways agreeing with the
previous model that demand shocks are the minor player. The gain, therefore, from
using capacity utilisation is trivial, so I will continue with equation (3).
Notes
12. Obviously this would not be the inflation rate for period 2, as there are other factors to consider.
Go to I. Introduction
Return to project index.
Email: gjs@swann39.freeserve.co.uk
13. That is, the coefficient lies within two standard deviations of zero and a null of equalling zero would not
be rejected.