The
High Middle Ages:
The
Thirteenth Century
The
pinnacle of the High Middle Ages, the thirteenth century was a period in which
the dynamic trends already under way during the two preceding centuries came to
fruition. Within the Church new reforming orders like the Franciscans and
Dominicans were founded and the papacy made even more unprecedented claims to
power. With these claims the papacy continued to come into conflict with
monarchs who had themselves gained in stature and power in certain areas,
particularly England and France. Commerce continued to thrive, but by this time
merchants, artisans, and even cities were organizing their own institutions,
like guilds and leagues, reflecting their growing power and permanency. The
culture of the Middle Ages flourished during this century. Magnificent Gothic
cathedrals, some started in the twelfth century, rose throughout Europe.
Universities expanded, becoming important centers of learning as well as
recruiting grounds for members of the growing state and ecclesiastical
bureaucracies. Medieval scholasticism dominated the period intellectually and
received its finest statement in the work of St. Thomas Aquinas.
In
this chapter some of the connections between religious, political, social, and
cultural trends of thirteenth-century Europe are examined. Some documents
concentrate primarily on theoretical and practical relations between the Church,
the state, and society. How did the papacy justify its claims over secular
authority? How did the Church react to the challenges presented by the growing
urban centers? How did the Church control its clergy, who had such concrete
contact with all classes in traditional society? How was the Church affected by
the growing body of and new respect for Classical law and thought?
The
documents also shed light on the relations between monarchs, nobles, and
towns-the three lay competitors for power. How did the strength of central
authority vary in different parts of Europe? How did monarchs, nobles, and towns
compete with one another for power and authority? How did the balance between
the monarchs, nobles, and towns shift in the Holy Roman Empire under Frederick
11? How did the newly assertive cities deal with the development of commerce and
urban growth, as seen in the formation of leagues and various urban institutions
such as guilds?
Finally,
the sources show how some of these relations were reflected in the culture and
society of the period. What constituted social injustice? What problems did
urban areas have with crime and violence? How was the position of the
aristocracy reflected in pictorial art? How was the new respect for Classical
law .
The
Outlaws of
Medieval
Legend: Social
Rank
and Injustice
Maurice
Keen
Today,
the social system of the Middle Ages seems unjust, particularly for the poor,
who suffered the most. Yet one must be careful in applying modern standards to
an earlier era. In the following selection Maurice Keen of Oxford argues that
the poor did not have such a critical view of the social system and the laws
that supported such a hierarchical structure. Rather, criticism was directed
toward corruption within the system. In his interpretation Keen makes creative
use Of evidence from medieval ballads and legends.
Consider:
The common view or ideal that justified the social system to the medieval mind,
what sort of behavior created a sense of injustice in the minds of medieval
people.
The
middle ages were profoundly respectful to hereditary rank and they did not
question its title to homage. They did on the other hand question the right of
those whose actions belied any nobility of mind to the enjoyment of the
privileges of noble status. They were not indignant against an unjust social
system, but they were indignant against unjust social superiors. The ballad
makers accepted this contemporary attitude and echoed it in their poems.
This
explains why the ballads have nothing to say of the economic exploitation of the
poor, of the tyranny of lords of manors whose bondmen were tied to the soil and
bound by immemorial custom to till their land for him. For we might expect, from
what we know of the social system of the countryside in the middle ages, to find
Robin, as the champion of the poor, freeing serfs from bondage, harbouring
runaway villeins in his band, and punishing the stewards of estates whose
conduct was every whit as harsh and unjust as that of the offices of the law.
But the middle ages did not view social injustice, as we do, in terms of the
exploitation of one class by another; they admired the class system as the
co-operation for the common well-being of the different estates of men. They
recognized three different classes in their society; the knights and lords,
whose business it was to protect Christendom in arms, the clerks who had charge
of its spiritual wellbeing and whose duty was prayer, and the common men whose
business it was to till the soil. Each rank had its obligation to discharge its
proper duties without complaint, and, in the case particularly of the first two
classes, not to abuse the privileges which its function gave it. That they were
made to 'swink and toil' gave the peasants no ground for complaint; their
occupation, as one preacher quaintly put it, lay in 'grobbynge about the erthe,
as erynge and dungynge and sowynge and harwying' and 'this schuld be do justlie
and for a good ende, withoute feyntise or falshede or gruechyngle of hire estaat'.
But those who failed to discharge their duties and abused their position had no
right to a
place
in the system, nor to the profits of association. 'They neither labour with the
rustics ... nor fight with the knights, nor pray and chant with the clergy;
therefore,' says the great Dominican, Bromyard, of such men 'they shall go with
their own abbot, of whose Order they are, namely the Devil, where no Order
exists but horror eternal.
The
law's object is ultimately to uphold social justice, and to the middle ages
social justice meant a hierarchical social system. The trouble came when those
who belonged to a high class used the wealth, which was given them to uphold
their proper rank, to corrupt the law and abuse it for their own profit. Their
ultimate sin was the use of their originally rightful riches to purchase more
than was their due. For this reason, those who were shocked by flagrant
injustice into attacking the accepted system criticized not the economic
oppression which is almost automatically implied, but the corruption of evil men
whose personal greed destroyed the social harmony of what they regarded as the
ideal system. The method which these men employed was to buy the law, and to
control by their position its application. It is for this reason that the outlaw
ballads, whose heroes are the champions of the poor, are silent about the
multitudinous economic miseries of the medieval peasant, and are concerned only
or at least chiefly with an endless feud against the corrupt representatives of
the law. Contemporary opinion diagnosed the disease which was gnawing at society
as the personal corruption of those in high rank; that such disease was the
inevitable accompaniment of their hierarchic system they simply could not see.
This is why the animus in the outlaw ballads is against oppression by those who
own the law, not against exploitation by those who own the land.
Life
in Cities:
Violence
and Fear
Jacques
Rossiaud
The
growth of cities after the eleventh century created what we now recognize as
typical urban problems. One such problem was keeping the peace. Cities in
Western Europe were often places of violence and fear As part of a trend toward
studying, social life, historians have increasingly studied crime and violence
in medieval cities. In the following selection Jacques Rossiaud analyzes violent
acts in the cities o Western Europe, emphasizing how urban violence fostered
anxiety.
Consider:
Who tended to commit most of the violent acts; possible explanations for urban
violence; what the effects of this violence might be.
The
history of the cities of Western Europe is shot through with episodes of
violence, fear, and revolution, episodes in which family honor, participation in
the municipal council, or working conditions were at stake. Such conflicts
opposed "magnate" and "popular" factions. In Italy they
opposed actual political parties dominated by clans, and in the bigger cities of
Flanders they turned into true class wars punctuated by massacres, exilings, and
destruction. Such conflicts were frequent between 1250 and 1330, and they
resulted everywhere in a defeat of the old rich land and an enlargement of
oligarchies. A second wave of unrest of a more clearly social character (the
dompi in Florence and Siena, the maillotins in Paris, and so forth) battered the
urban world in the late fourteenth century. The defeat of the lower orders did
not put an end to the tensions, which were transformed into an occasional brief
terror, here and there, but were more usually expressed in continual but muted,
"atomized" conflicts difficult to distinguish from common delinquency
in the documentation. Stones thrown at night through a master's windows, a
creditor brutalized, a brawl between two rival groups of workers were easily
ascribed to ordinary violence by the judges.
In
other words, many city-dwellers, even if they lived through long and difficult
periods of tension, escaped the horrors of riots and repression, but they all
had to face an atmosphere of violence on an almost daily basis. There is little
need to accumulate examples: in Florence, Venice, Paris, Lille, Dijon, Avignon,
Tours, or Foix, the judicial archives reveal an impressive series of
cold-blooded vendettas, of chaudes mNjes between individuals or groups settled
with knives or iron-tipped sticks, and of rapes, often collective, that marked
for life poor girls beaten and dragged from their rooms at night.
These
violent acts were for the most part committed by youths or adult men, often of
modest social condition, but who were indistinguishable from law-abiding
citizens.
Wine-drunkenness
was often an excuse does not explain everythinLy, nor do the arms that everyone
carried in spite of municipal ordinances. The example came from on high: even in
Reims at the beginning of the fourteenth century, the judges were incapable of
keeping clans from resolving their quarrels by means of arms. However, civic
violence (executions, torture, forcing a criminal to run through the city
streets as the crowd jeered and struck him) was offered as a spectacle, and the
domestic moral code allowed blows. justice, what is more, did not inspire
belief; it was more dreaded than appreciated, and it was inefficient and costly.
When he was scoffed at, the individual turned to immediate vengeance. He did so
to safeguard his honor: it was in the name of honor that young men punished
girls who, to their minds, transgressed its canons. Like violence, honor was a
value widespread in urban societies: prominent citizens were called "honor-
able."
There was no reputation without honor and no honor without authority. The
richman's wealth and friends lent support to his honor; the working man without
wealth held his reputation to be an essential capital.
Violence
fostered anxiety. On occasion the notables denounced it, but they did not really
seek to extirpate it (either in Venice or Dijon). For humble folk this fear
added to other obsessions-of being abandoned amid general indifference, as with
Dame Poverty, whom jean de Meun described as covered with an old sack, 11 a bit
apart from the others ... crouched down and hunched over like a poor dog,"
sad, shamed, and unloved.
Solitude
Georges
Duby
Whether
in urban or rural areas, people of the High Middle Ages spent much of their
everyday lives in the company of others. What we in our times think of as
privacy was not quite the same in medieval society. Not only were living spaces
more communal, but people were expected to work, play, and travel in groups. In
the following selection A History of Private Life, Georges Duby describes this
crowded, communal society and the difficulties facing anyone seeking solitude.
Consider:
How groups formed in various occupations and activities; how Duby analyzes
private space; the problems facing an individual longing for solitude.
People
crowded together cheek by jowl, living in promiscuity, sometimes in the midst of
a mob. In feudal residences there was no room for individual solitude, except
perhaps in the moment of death. When people ventured outside the domestic
enclosure, they did so in groups. No journey could be made by fewer than two
people, and if it happened that they were not related, they bound themselves by
rites of brotherhood, creating an artificial family that lasted as long as the
journey required. By age seven, at which time young aristocratic males were
considered persons of sex, they left the woman's world and embarked upon a life
of adventure. Yet throughout their lives they remained surrounded, in the strong
sense of the word-whether they were dedicated to the service of God and sent to
study with a schoolmaster or joined a group of other young men in aping the
gestures of a leader, their new father, whom they followed whenever he left his
house to defend his rights by force of arms or force of words or to hunt in his
forests. Their apprenticeship over, new knights received their arms as a group,
a mob organized as a family. (Generally the lord's son was dubbed along with the
sons of the vassals.) From that time forth the young knights were always
together, linked in glory and in shame, vouching for and standing as hostage for
one another. As a group, accompanied by servants and often by priests, they
raced from tourney to tourney, court to court, skirmish to skirmish, displaying
their loyalties by showing the colors or shouting the same rallying cry. The
devotion of these young comrades enveloped their leader in an indispensable
mantle of domestic familiarity, an itinerant household.
Thus,
in feudal society, private space was divided, composed of two distinct areas:
one fixed, enclosed, attached to the hearth; the other mobile, free to move
through public
space,
yet embodying the same hierarchies and held together by the same controls.
Within this mobile cell peace and order were maintained by a power whose mission
was to organize a defense against the intrusion of the public authorities, for
which purpose an invisible wall, as solid as the enclosure that surrounded the
house, was erected against the outside world. This power enveloped and
restrained the individuals of the household, subjecting them to a common
discipline. Power meant constraint. And if private life meant secrecy, it was a
secrecy shared by all members of the household, hence fragile and easily
violated. If private life meant independence, it was independence of a
collective sort. In the eleventh and twelfth centuries collective privacy did
exist. But can we detect any signs of personal privacy within the collective
privacy?
Feudal
society was so granular in structure, composed of such compact curds, that any
individual who attempted to remove himself from the close and omnipresent
conviviality, to be alone, to construct his own private enclosure, to cultivate
his garden, immediately became an object of either suspicion or admiration,
regarded as either a rebel or a hero and in either case considered
"foreign"-the antithesis of "private." The person who stood
apart, even if his intention was not deliberately to commit evil, was inevitably
destined to do so, for his very isolation made him more vulnerable to the
Enemy's attacks. No one would run such a risk who was not deviant or possessed
or mad; it was commonly believed that solitary wandering was a symptom of
insanity. Men and women who traveled the roads without escort were believed to
offer themselves up as prey, so it was legitimate to take everything they had.
In any case, it was a pious work to place them back in some community,
regardless of what they might say, to restore them by force to that clearly
ordered and well-managed world where God intended them to be, a world composed
of private enclosures and of the public spaces between them, through which
people moved only in cortege.
Ecological
Conditions
and
Demographic Change
David
Herlihy
Most
historians feel that the medieval expansion ended between 1300 and 1350 and that
changes occurred that marked the following century as one of contraction,
disruption, and decline. Traditionally, these changes have been analyzed from
political, military, and religious perspectives. In the following selection
David Herlihy of Harvard focuses on the economic aspects of this change,
particularly the economic limitations that prevented the medieval expansion from
continuing much beyond the thirteenth century.
Consider:
Obstacles hindering economic expansion by 1300; the social and political effects
that might have stemmed from these economic changes; other factors that might
account for the end of the medieval expansion.
Medieval
expansion, however, never achieved a true breakthrough, never reached what some
economists today term the stage of "takeoff," in which a built-in
capacity for continuing growth is developed. By around 1300, certain obstacles
were beginning to hinder economic expansion. One was the relative stagnation of
technology. In spite of important technological discoveries that introduced the
Middle Ages, peasants in 1300 were working the land much as their ancestors had
several centuries before. However, technological stagnation alone does not seem
to have imposed a rigid ceiling on growth. Paradoxically, many peasants in the
late thirteenth century were not working the soil according to the best known
and available methods. Their chief handicap was not lack of knowledge but lack
of capital, for the best methods were based upon the effective use of cattle to
supply both labor and manure. Insofar as we can judge, many small cultivators of
the thirteenth century could not afford cattle and had to work their plots with
their own unaided and inefficient efforts.
A
second limitation upon expansion was the failure to develop institutions and
values that would maintain appropriate levels of investment, especially in
agriculture. In spite of the growth of cities, a large part of Europe's lands
was controlled by military and clerical aristocracies, which were not likely to
reinvest their profits received in rent. The great landlords were rather prone
to spend their rents on conspicuous but economically barren forms of consumption
such as manor houses, castles, churches, wars, the maintenance of a lavish style
of living. They were also likely to demand from the towns money in loans for
such unproductive expenditures.
A
third limiting factor seems to have been the growing scarcity of resources,
especially good land. As the best soils were taken under cultivation, the still
growing population had to rely increasingly upon poorer, marginal lands, which
required more effort and capital to assure a good return. The European economy
was burdened by a growing saturation in the use of its readily available
resources, and it had neither the technology nor the capital to improve its
returns from what it possessed. In the opinion of many historians today, this
saturation in the use of resources not only ended the economic advance of the
central Middle Ages but precipitated a profound demographic and economic crisis
in the fourteenth century.
Chapter
Questions
1.
Some historians have described the thirteenth century as the period in which
Medieval civilization attained a remarkable balance. In what ways was this
period so balanced?
2.
In what ways were the main characteristics of the thirteenth century simply a
further extension of trends already evident during the eleventh and twelfth
centuries? What new developments appeared during the thirteenth century?
3.
What evidence does the chapter provide of the struggle for authority that
persisted through this period?