The
National State, Nationalism, and Imperialism:
1850-1914
Between
1850 and 1914 Europe was characterized politically by the development of the
national state, the spread of nationalism, and the rise of the 11 new
imperialism." The development of the national state took place after 1848.
Governments, responding to economic and social pressures, increased their
involvement in the economic and social life of their countries. This was
apparent both in liberal England and in more conservative France under Louis
Napoleon. There were similar trends during the national unification movements in
Italy and particularly in Germany, where the state took on a wide range of new
functions.
Nationalism
had deep roots, notably in the experience of and reactions to the French
Revolution and the Napoleonic invasions. Nationalism also played a central role
in the revolutions of 1848. During the second half of the nineteenth century,
nationalism continued to grow and to be capitalized upon by national
governments. The most striking manifestations of nationalism came in the
successful unification movements in Italy and Germany.
The rise of the new imperialism occurred in the last three decades of the
nineteenth century. The European powers engaged in a sudden quest for control
over new territories in Asia and Africa. Explorers, missionaries, traders,
troops, and government officials quickly followed one another into these lands
and established direct political control. In this process the West greatly
increased its dominance over much of the rest of the world, bringing Western
culture and institutions to the indigenous societies whether they wanted it or
not.
The
sources in this chapter explore each of these three developments. Some of the
documents concentrate on the growth of the national state, particularly in
Germany, where the authoritarian government expanded in an effort to adapt to
the social and economic pressures of the times, and France, where forces for
radical change were still strong. Some of the questions addressed are: How did
the government in Germany react to demands for social legislation? What was the
role of conservative forces in the German unification process, and how did their
dominance affect the subsequent history of Germany? Other documents concern
nationalism, particularly its meaning, its appeal, and its connections to
liberalism and conservatism. How did nationalism change over the nineteenth
century? What role did nationalism play in the unification movements in Germany
and Italy? How was nationalism tied to the new imperialism of the period?
Finally, most of the selections deal with imperialism, for not only was
imperialism of far-reaching significance for much of the world, it has been a
topic of considerable debate among historians. What were the nationalistic and
economic motives for imperialism? What were some of the attitudes toward
imperialism, particularly as reflected in materials glorifying it as a Christian
and humanitarian movement? How is imperialism understood from a Marxist
perspective? What were some of the consequences of imperialism?
Throughout
these selections there is evidence for an increasing competitiveness among
European states and political strains within those states. As will be seen in
Chapter 11, these contributed to the outbreak of World War I and the revolutions
that accompanied it.
Speeches
on Pragmatism and State Socialism
Otto
von Bismarck
The
revolutions of 1848 were ultimately a blow to idealistic reform. Therea er,
governments pursued more limited goals. They tended to resort to more
authoritarian measures, to avoid doctrinaire policies, and even to adopt certain
programs of opposing groups in the hopes of weakening determined opposition to
the government. Otto von Bismarck (1815-1898) did this in Germany. Born into a
noble Prussian family, Bismarck rose to the position of chief minister under the
king in 1862. The first selection below is from an 1862 speech to the Reichstag,
in which he argues that the idealism of 1848 must be replaced by a conservative
realism.
Bismarck
remained in power until 1890. During this time he and his conservative
supporters faced opposition from some liberals and from a growing number of
socialists representing the working class. In the 1880s Bismarck supported some
of the workers' demands for social insurance and pushed through such legislation
as the German Workers' Insurance Laws. The remaining excerpts below Bismarck's
speeches indicate the rationale behind these policies.
Consider:
What Bismarck means when he says the great quesilions of the day will be decided
by iron and blood; how Bismarck justifies his support of Òsocialist"
policies; why Bismarck would support such policies; what conservatives have to
gain and who stands to lose by enactment of these policies.
IRON
AND BLOOD
.
. . It is true that we can hardly escape complications in Germany, although we
do not seek them. Germany does not look to Prussia's liberalism, but to her
power. The south German States -Bavaria, Wfirttemberg, and Baden -would like to
indulge in liberalism. and because of that no one will assign Prussia's role to
theml Prussia must collect her forces and hold them in reserve for an opportune
moment, which has already come and gone several times. Since the Treaty of
Vienna, our frontiers have not been favorably designed for a healthy body
politic. Not by speeches and majorities will the great questions of the day be
decided -that was the mistake of 1848 and 1849 -but by iron and blood.
STATE
SOCIALISM
Herr
Richter has called attention to the responsibility of the State for what it
does. But it is my opinion that the State can also be responsible for what it
does not do. I do not think that doctrines like those of 'Laissez-faire,
laissezaller,' 'Pure Manchesterdom in politics,' 'He who is not strong enough to
stand must be knocked down and trodden to the ground.-To him that hath shall be
given, and from him that hath not shall be taken away even that which he
hath,'-that doctrines like these should be applied in the State, and especially
in a monarchically, paternally governed State. On the other hand, I believe that
those who profess horror at the intervention of the State for the protection of
the weak lay themselves open to the suspicion that they are desirous of using
their strength -be it that of capital, that of rhetoric, or whatever it be-for
the benefit of a section, for the oppression of the rest, for the introduction
of party domination, and that they will be chagrined as soon as this design is
disturbed by any action of the Government.
The
White Man's Burden
Rudyard
Kipling
Imperialism
was often glorified both by those actively involved in it and by the public at
home. Part of this glorification involved perceiving imperialism as a Christian
and nationalistic venture. More broadly it involved portraying imperialism as a
heroic deed carried out by idealistic leaders of Western civilization in an
effort to spread the "benefits" of "true civilization" to
'less advanced" peoples of the world. One of the most popular expressions
of this is found in the writings of Rudyard Kipling (1865-1936), particularly in
his poem "The White Man's Burden," written in 1899 to celebrate the
American annexation of the Philippines.
Consider:
What Kipling means by "the White Man's burden"; how Kipling justifies
imperialism; why such a justification might be so appealing.
Take
up the White Man's burden
Send
forth the best ye breed
Go,
bind your sons to exile
To
serve your captives' need;
To
wait, in heavy harness,
On
fluttered folk and wild
Your
new-caught sullen peoples,
Half
devil and half child.
Take
up the White Man's burden
In
patience to abide,
To
veil the threat of terror
And
check the show of pride;
By
open speech and simple,
An
hundred times made plain,
To
seek another's profit
And
work another's gain.
Take
up the White Man's burden
The
savage wars of peace
Fill
full the mouth of Famine,
And
bid the sickness cease;
And
when your goal is nearest
(The
end for others sought)
Watch
sloth and heathen folly
Bring
all your hope to nought.
Take
up the White Man's burden
No
iron rule of kings,
But
toil of serf and sweeper -
The
tale of common things.
The
ports ye shall not enter,
The
roads ye shall not tread,
Go,
make them with your living
And
mark them with your dead.
Take
up the White Man's burden,
And
reap his old reward
The
blame of those ye better
The
hate of those ye guard
The
cry of hosts ye humour
(Ah,
slowlyl) toward the light:
"Why
brought ye us from bondage,
Our
loved Egyptian night?"
Take
up the White Man's burden -
Ye
dare not stoop to less
Nor
call too loud on Freedom
To
cloke your weariness.
By
all ye will or whisper,
By
all ye leave or do,
The
silent sullen peoples
Shall
weigh your God and you.
Take
up the White Man's burdenI
Have
done with childish days
The
lightly-proffered laurel,
The
easy ungrudged praise:
Comes
now, to search your manhood
Through
all the thankless years,
Cold,
edged with dear-bought wisdom,
The
judgment of your peers.
Nationalism:
Myth and Reality
Boyd
Shafer
Although
growing nationalism was a general pattern during the nineteenth century, the
forms that nationalism took and its actual meaning differed over time and in
various areas. Indeed, "nationalism" is a term that historians have
usually used quite loosely, adding to problems of understanding its meaning. In
the following selection, Boyd Shafer attempts to define nationalism by listing
ten characteristics it embodies.
Consider:
What it would mean to be a German or Italian "nationalist" during the
second half of the nineteenth century, according to Shafer's definition of
nationalism; what the political implications are of nationalism so defined; the
elements of this definition that make nationalism such a powerful force.
1.
A certain defined (often vaguely) unit of territory (whether possessed or
coveted).
2.
Some common cultural characteristics such as language (or widely
understood languages), customs, manners, and literature (folk tales and lore are
a beginning). If an individual believes he shares these, and wishes to continue
sharing them, he is usually said to be a member of the nationality.
3.
Some common dominant social (as Christian) and economic (as capitalistic
or recently communistic) institutions.
4.
A common independent or sovereign government (type does not matter) or
the desire for one. The "principle" that each nationality should be
separate and independent is involved here.
5.
A belief in a common history (it can be invented) and in a common origin
(often mistakenly conceived to be racial in nature).
6.
A love or esteem for fellow nationals (not necessarily as individuals).
7.
A devotion to the entity (however little comprehended) called the nation,
which embodies the common territory, culture, social and economic institutions,
government, and the fellow nationals, and which is at the same time (whether
organism or not) more than their sum.
8.
A common pride in the achievements (often the military more than the
cultural) of this nation and a common sorrow in its tragedies (particularly its
defeats).
9.
A disregard for or hostility to other (not necessarily all) like groups,
especially if these prevent or seem to threaten the separate national existence.
10.
A hope that the nation will have a great and glorious future (usually in
territorial expansion) and become supreme in some way (in world power if the
nation is already large).
A
Sterner Plan for Italian Unity: Nationalism, Liberalism . and Conservatism
Raymond
Grew
During
the first half of the nineteenth century, nationalism was most often connected
to liberalism. After the revolutions of 1848 there were increasing ties between
nationalism and conservatism, particularly in the movements for national
unification. In the following selection Raymond Grew, an advocate of comparative
history from the University of Michigan, analyzes the relationships among
nationalism, liberalism, and conservatism in a comparative context.
Consider:
How nationalism could appeal to both liberals and conservatives; why, during the
second half of the nineteenth century, liberal ideals were often sacrificed in
the name of nationalism; using this and the preceding document, the bases on
which nationalism might have been opposed.
Insofar
as politics was the public battle of ideas and interests, then nationalism was a
denial of politics. For in stressing the values of unity, loyalty, and duty,
nationalism saw political dispute as a source of weakness. It denied that there
was conflict in the true interests of classes, groups or regions. The effect of
nationalism was therefore inherently conservative in that it provided reason for
supporting anyone thought to wield the power of the state effectively in behalf
of national unity and strength, Disraeli or Gladstone, Napoleon III or Bismarck.
Since order and unity, the cry of the political conservative, are essential to a
strong state, and since, to the nationalist, most worthy ends required that
strength, the nationalist was always tempted under pressure to move toward the
political right, to sacrifice liberty to unity, discussion to authority, ends to
means.
Yet
the origins of nationalism were usually liberal and reformist; for everywhere it
was a demand for change, the doctrine of the modernizers who, while they had too
much to lose to want a social revolution, were selfconsciously aware that theirs
was an "underdeveloped" country. Nationalism could make its denial of
politics effective because its ends were so clear, so easily defined in the
model of the modern state. For the French that model had been England; for the
Italians it was England and France. Italian nationalists were usually liberals,
but their liberalism was primarily an admiration for the achievements of the
liberal state. Because their model already existed, they looked directly to it,
anxious to achieve an efficient bureaucracy, a responsible government, a
progressive economic structure, all based on accepted and universally applied
laws. Nationalism was a program to obtain these things quickly, not to evolve
toward them but, if necessary, to superimpose them. The hurry to achieve these
goals where nationalism itself was seriously opposed made a doctrinaire concern
for means appear pedantic and unrealistic. Italian nationalists needed nothing
so brutal as cynicism to justify "postponement" of controversy or the
choice of practical means, though often this meant whittling away at the
practices necessary to viable liberalism.
xGerman
Unification
Hajo
Holborn
As
in the I case of Italy, nationalism in Germany during the first half of the
nineteenth century was closely connected to liberalism. This was particularly so
in the early stages of the revolutions of 1848. But with the failure of liberal
nationalists to gain the concrete changes they strove for, steps toward
unification over the next two decades followed a different path. In the
following selection, Hajo Holborn, a noted historian of Germany, analyzes the
significance of that path for German history until the outbreak of World War I
in 1914.
Consider:
The ways in which liberalism was sacrificed during this period; how the relation
between liberalism and nationalism was affected by the position of different
social groups in Germany; how Bismarck's social policies support Holborn's
interpretation.
The
achievement of German unity gave Bismarck the power to force the German liberals
to decide whether they were more eager to see unity or liberty achieved in
Germany. The majority of them proved willing to compromise with Bismarck. Since
centralization went rather far under the new constitution he needed the liberal
movement to some extent to counterbalance the particularistic German forces
represented chiefly by the German princes. The constitution of the new German
empire was, therefore, a bit more centralized and more liberal than Bismarck
wished, but he maintained control of the crucial policy-making positions. No
decisive power over military and foreign affairs by the constituted popular
bodies was allowed in the second German empire. Bismarck made all sorts of
concessions in the field of social and economic reform but was absolutely
adamant with regard to the powers of the parliament. The direction of foreign
and military matters remained a privilege of the Crown.
The
pseudo -constitutional character of the new German empire was even more
accentuated when in 1878 Bismarck decided to give up free trade and imposed a
policy protecting the interests of the Prussian Junker agrarians against the
importation of cheap Russian and American grain while at the same time
introducing tariffs benefiting the growing German iron industries. just as in
1866 and 1871 the German liberals had had to sacrifice the core of their
political faith, so they were forced to jettison the major part of their
economic program after 1878. The leading industrial groups of German society
readily accepted a protectionist trade policy, and the unity of the liberal
bourgeoisie crumbled. Thirty years after German liberalism had burst into
existence in the Revolution of 1848, it ceased to be an independent political
movement. Thereafter the majority of the German bourgeoisie, if they did not,
like the higher bourgeoisie, become absolute supporters of the regime, were
driven to further concession and compromise. The appearance of a powerful
socialist workers' movement extinguished the last remaining fervor for reform
among, the liberal bourgeoisie and made them take cover under the wings of the
established government. The second German empire was founded "by blood and
iron" and socially stabilized by "iron and grain." For more than
fifty years the German political scene was overshadowed by the alliance of the
"barons of the halm" and the "barons of the smokestack," who
maintained the army and bureaucracy in power.
Imperialism
V.
I. Lenin
Imperialism
has been interpreted from a number of perspectives since the early twentieth
century. The way that scholars view imperialism often reveals much about their
own political and ideological views. Some of the earlier interpretations, such
as those by J. H. Hobson and V. I. Lenin, were economic. They criticized
imperialism as an outgrowth of capitalism, Hobson from the perspective of a
liberal socialist, Lenin as a Marxist theorist and political leader. Indeed for
Lenin, imperialism was not only economically determined, it was also a crucial
element in a Marxist explanation of how capitalism was evolving historically.
This view is illustrated in the following selection from his Imperialism,
written in 1916 when Lenin was a Bolshevik leader in exile and not yet in power.
Consider:
Why imperialism is connected to monopoly capitalism; the interest groups that
would benefit most from imperialism; in Lenin's view, why England was the
greatest imperial nation and why other nations would want to join in the
imperial struggle.
Imperialism
emerged as the development and direct continuation of the fundamental
characteristics of capitalism in general. But capitalism only became capitalist
imperialism at a definite and very high stage of its development, when certain
of its fundamental characteristics began to change into their opposites, when
the features of the epoch of transition from capitalism to a higher social and
economic system had taken shape and revealed themselves in all spheres.
Economically, the main thing in this process is the displacement of capitalist
free competition by capitalist monopoly. Free competition is the basic feature
of capitalism, and of commodity production generally; monopoly is the exact
opposite of free competition, but we have seen the latter being transformed into
monopoly before our eyes, creating large-scale industry and forcing out small
industry, replacing large-scale by still larger-scale industry, and carrying
concentration of production and capital to the point where out of it has grown
and is growing monopoly: cartels, syndicates and trusts, and merging with them,
the capital of a dozen or so banks, which manipulate thousands of millions. At
the same time the monopolies, which have grown out of free competition, do not
eliminate the latter, but exist above it and alongside it, and thereby give rise
to a number of very acute, intense antagonisms, frictions and conflicts.
Monopoly is the transition from capitalism to a higher system. . . .
We
must give a definition of imperialism that will include the following five of
its basic features:
(1)
the concentration of production and capital has developed to such a high stage
that it has created monopolies which play a decisive role in economic life; (2)
the merging of bank capital with industrial capital, and the creation, on the
basis of this "finance capital". of a financial oligarchy; (3) the
export of capital as distinguished from the export of commodities acquires
exceptional importance; (4) the formation of international monopolist capitalist
associations which share the world among themselves, and (5) the territorial
division of the whole world among the biggest capitalist powers is completed.
Imperialism is capitalism at that stage of development at which the dominance of
monopolies and finance capital is established; in
which
the export of capital has acquired pronounced importance; in which the division
of the world among the international trusts has begun, in which the division of
all territories of the globe among the biggest capitalist powers has been
completed.
Imperialism
as a
Nationalistic
Phenomenon
Carlton
Hayes
Although
the economic interpretation of imperialism has not lost its strength, other
views have been offered recently as supplements and sometimes as direct alter
natives to an economic interpretation. A direct alternative appears in the
following selection by Carlton J. H. Hayes. One of the earliest historians to
develop a sophisticated understanding of nationalism, Hayes argues that economic
motives were at best secondary; on the whole, imperialism was a nationalistic
phenomenon.
Consider:
The evidence Hayes uses to reject economic interpretations of nationalism; how
Lenin might reply to this interpretation; the ways in which this view ts with
the documents on nationalism in this chapter.
The
founding of new colonial empires and the fortifying of old ones antedated the
establishment of neo- mercantilism, and that the economic arguments adduced in
support of imperialism seem to have been a rationalization ex post facto. In the
main, it was not Liberal parties, with their super abundance of industrials and
bankers, who sponsored the outward imperialistic thrusts of the '70 1 s and
early '80's. Instead, it was Conservative parties, with a preponderantly
agricultural clientele notoriously suspicious of moneylenders and big business,
and, above all, it was patriotic professors and publicists regardless of
political affiliation and unmindful of personal economic interest. These put
forth the economic arguments which eventually drew bankers and traders and
industrialists into the imperialist camp.
Basically
the new imperialism was a nationalistic phenomenon. It followed hard upon the
national wars which created an all-powerful Germany and a united Italy, which
carried Russia within sight of Constantinople, and which left England fearful
and France eclipsed. It expressed a resulting psychological reaction, an ardent
desire to maintain or recover national prestige. France sought compensation for
European loss in oversea gain. England would offset her European isolation by
enlarging and glorifying the British Empire. Russia, halted in the Balkans,
would turn anew to Asia, and before long Germany and Italy would show the world
that the prestige they had won by might inside Europe they were entitled to
enhance by imperial exploits outside. The lesser powers, with no great prestige
at stake, managed to get on without any new imperialism, though Portugal and
Holland displayed a revived pride in the empires they already possessed and the
latter's was administered with renewed vigor. . . .
Most
simply, the sequence of imperialism after 1870 appears to have been, first,
pleas for colonies on the ground of national prestige; second, getting them;
third, disarming critics by economic argument; and fourth, carrying this into
effect and relating the results to the neo-mercantilism of tariff protection and
social legislation at home.
The
Effects of Imperialism
David
Landes
Earlier
in the twentieth century, historians, even those quite critical of imperialism,
saw its impact mainly in European terms. In recent decades, the effects of
imperialism have been viewed more from the perspective of native populations
subject to imperial control. This has led to a more subtle understanding of
imperialism and helps explain some of the persisting problems between the West
and many "underdeveloped" or "third world" countries. This
perspective is illustrated in the following selection by David Landes, an
economic historian from Harvard. Here he focuses on Egypt.
Consider:
The nature of the double standard described by Landes; how this double standard
affected people's and nations' attitudes; whether this view fits best with the
nationalistic or the economic interpretation o imperialism.
While
most Europeans in Egypt lived according to principles, they had two sets of
principles: the same rules did not apply in dealing with the in-group of
Westerners and the out-group of natives. Some Europeans drew the line between
the two societies more sharply than others. There were those for whom the Turk
was of his nature treacherous, Moslem justice hopelessly corrupt, the native
population mean and despicable. There were others who found the Turk not
deliberately false, but lazy and neglectful; who recognized the validity of
Moslem law within the framework of Egyptian society, but felt that it offered
little protection to foreigners habituated to other codes and that the native
tribunals were excessively submissive to government pressure; who had more
sympathy than scorn for the Arab, and deplored his inadaptability to the
discipline and precision implicit in modern industry and trade. Some saw in
every Egyptian a potential enemy whose ill faith required constant vigilance and
strong remedies; others looked upon the natives as children whose fumblings and
misconduct were best handled by the paternal chastisement of their European
friends and protectors. All, however, were agreed that Egyptian society was
backward and Egyptian civilization inferior; that the European could not afford
to submit to the customs of the country, but that the Egyptian would have to
learn the ways and accept the justice of the European; that the standards of
behaviour accepted in Europe, the values of honesty, fair play, reasonableness,
and so on that shaped - at least in principle the social and business relations
of the West, had to be modified to fit the circumstances of a strange
environment. . . .
More
than anything, more even than the enormous material costs of imperialism, it was
the imposition of inferior social and moral status that shaped the reaction of
the Egyptian to the European. Actually, the one implies the other: material
exploitation is difficult if not impossible without the sanction of a double set
of values and a corresponding double code of behaviour; if they were not there
to begin with, the exploiter would have to create them. The fact remains,
however, that in the many-sided impact of imperialism, it is the injury to
self-respect that hurts most. It is the resentment aroused by spiritual
humiliation that gives rise to an irrational response to rational exploitation.
The apparently unreasonable, and certainly unprofitable, resistance of many of
the world's underdeveloped countries today to Western business enterprise makes
sense only in this context.
Chapter
Questions On Italy and Germany
1.
What historical links are there between nationalism, the national state,
and imperialism during the nineteenth century? How might all three be connected
to industrialization, discussed in the previous chapter?
2.
How would you explain the rise of imperialism in the late nineteenth
century?
3.
In what ways have some of our perceptions of imperialism changed since
the late nineteenth century?