Military Keynesian

 

 


The debate of whether capitalism has triumphed over communism or a socialist society has yet to be answered by historiography. The unfolding events of the late 20th century provided models of political behavior and policy that have been previously unseen. This is most expressively found in the disintegration of the USSR. One important aspect of this disintegration has been the economic impact in Russia to its citizens and also to other economies around the world. How will the politics of Mikhail Gorbachev and perestroika ultimately affect the economic systems of the world? How will the ideas that shaped this political move be interpreted? From this type of question, intellectual historians have tried to reduce the predominating view that represents a particular period to an ideology. Given the presupposition that actual political activity occurs out of the predominate ideology, intellectual historians assign an dominate ideology to the actions of leadership. This type of scholarship usually emphasizes the ideas that move politics. Political in nature, ideas of the “good society” are expressed in governmental degrees and legislation. Given this position, historians can attempt to focus on the ideas that predominate a particular era, decade, or year. Within the sphere of economic history in America, historians have focused on the economic ideology of Keynes during the period following the great depression through the early 1940’s.

One such focus is given by Richard Aledstein. In an article presented in The Journal of American History, Alestein proposes an “alternative interpretation” that he believes “captures” the meaning of The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, written by John M Keynes. This “alternative interpretation” is in response to Robert Shidelsky’s article of 1979. Shidelsky’s article presents a viewpoint of Keynesian economics as being the crucial factor that avoided America and Britain from taking an extreme political move toward socialism or totalitarianism. While the emphasis on the economic causation of events in history is obvious, Shidelsky did manage to ask a critical question as to whether Keynesian economics, that predominated in American economic policy from the 1940’s to the 1970’s in his view, had only limited usefulness given the changing world conditions. Equally, he brought awareness to the fact that the answer as to which system of economic control is best for society, had not been answered. The conditions that Keynes had predicted, such as an politically impartial ruling elite, had not evolve in the political and economic history of mankind.
Given this background, Alestein presents an “alternative interpretation” that focuses upon the use of Keynesian economic theory in the “maturing ideology of managerial control.” He states that American managerialists sought “to achieve an effective merger of state and economy based on scientific principles of administration” that could be “employed in the public interest.” This control was sought by the administrations of Hoover and Roosevelt for two reasons. One, the government was trying to exert control over the economy in an effort to control the effects of the Great Depression. Two, an adequate economic theory might also be used to prevent wide swings in the business cycle and thus avoid another depression or severe recession. In a convincing manner, Alestein proceeds to elaborate how the experiences of World War I provided policy makers with the “experience of planning.” This planning or control was demonstrated during the war with the effective use of planning industrial production and distribution. Alestein also convincingly argues that the control that was granted the “managers” was linked during World War I to the goal of victory. Thus, corporations and industries, as well as individuals, subsumed their personal or corporate goals to a goal of victory in the war. The ideology “to win the war” predominated America’s economic policy legislation.

With the onslaught of the Great Depression, however, there existed a need for managerialists to find some unifying ideology by which the nation could reverse the effects of the severe economic distress that existed. This ideology was reflected in the administrative actions of the Hoover and Roosevelt administrations. For Hoover, economic stability could be obtained by an “active cooperation between business and government.” This is clearly collaborated by the administrative actions of Hoover in response to the stock market crash of 1929. As Albert Romasco has written, Hoover attempted to deal with the crisis in two forms. One was to advance an optimistic ideological position that the swings in the business cycle could be controlled by coordinating and directing the nation’s businesses through cooperation or “collectivism.” By calling on business leaders to hold wages at present levels and by maintaining present expansion plans, the nation would avoid a deepening of the depression. The second ideal was to encourage state and local governments to stimulate construction projects. These ideals, however, were never realized and conditions continued to deteriorate. As Adelstein states, “When they failed him, Hoover was lost.”

With the election of Roosevelt, a consistent managerial ideology similar to Hoover emerged, albeit in a different verbiage. For Roosevelt, a “war against the depression” was key. By eliciting the nation’s industries and business leadership to fight this war, Roosevelt and his policy makers believed that the effects of the depression could be controlled. The first policy to be enacted in this war was the establishment of the National Industrial Recovery Act, also known as the NRA. Adelstein states that the purpose of this bureaucracy was “to expand purchasing power by creating artificial scarcity in the midst of overcapacity, setting minimum prices in some industries and limits on production in others.” The problem was that the planners in this case had “no plan.” This manifested itself in the failure of the NRA, which was interestingly declared unconstitutional by the Supreme Court. As Michael Weinstein has pointed out, the NIRA “codes were a significant and independent contractionary influence,” and that, while conjectural, the “NIRA-induced inflation” prevented the potential rate of growth during this period and keep unemployment at higher levels.

For Adelstein, this course of action was not the only way to combat the depression. He suggests in his paper, that as early as 1930, Keynesian economic theory was being debated. However, the aversion of Roosevelt to debit spending and his own unwillingness to commit to a “strategic plan for the NRA” caused the rhetoric of a “war against the depression” to become useless as an ideological control mechanism. The result was numerous violations of the NRA codes and the ultimate demise of the NRA. The dilemma for the economic managers therefore remained. How could “managers” or planners use the power of the federal government to foster full employment and a growing economy? This problem was further complicated by Roosevelt’s political ideology that stressed the the ability to make massive expenditures by the federal government in times of peace was unconstitutional. Thus he avoided many attempts to apply Keynesian economics to fighting the “war against the depression.” From this, Adelstein proposes that the Keynesian strategy would have avoided the problems inherent in the ideology that was legislated in programs like the NRA.

As a result of the lack of successful “planning,” the economy before World War II continued in its sluggish condition with a recession in late 1937 and early 1938. While Keynesian economic ideology continued to be pressed during the 1930’s by policy makers and planners, Roosevelt and others continued to attack the problem by resorting to economic rehtoric on the value of cooperation among industries and their responsibility to the overall economic health of the nation. The federal government was only to act as enforcer of economic manipulation through legislation like the Fair Labor Standards Act and the second Agricultural Adjustment Act. As Adelstein points out, the determined effort to control the economic life of America resulted in a “vast expansion of the regulatory powers of the national state.” By holding to an ideological stance that the government could not incur debt in times of peace by expenditures on public construction projects, the nation could not regain the economic stability of the New Era of the 1920’s.

It is at this point that Adelstein presents his most basic and provoking argument. He suggests that had Roosevelt adopted a Keynesian economic ideology in the early 1930’s, recovery from the depression would have been achieved more quickly and without intrusive price controls and restraints. Adelstein recognizes that this would have called for a serious redefining of the role of the federal government. The issue would have been based and debated on “the division between Washington and the states of the authority to tax and spend.” The authority of the federal government to spend on public construction projects, which had been placed in the responsibility of states and localities by the Framers of the Constitution, would have been a far better battle to fight than the battle to have the authority to plan, Adelstein suggests. In a provocative statement, Adelstein says, “Roosevelt’s commitment to the macroeconomics of war precluded the institutional experimentation and reform that would have made possible the far more modest control implied by Keynes’ macroeconomics of peace.” While Keynesian ideology did become more standard among the planners during World War II, Adelstein refers to this ideology as “military Keynesianism.” An ideology that he says has dominated the economic life of America since W.W.II. Twice in the paper, he suggests that Roosevelt chose the macroeconomics of war over the macroeconomics of peace.

It is the last suggestion of Adelstein that is perhaps of most importance for economic historiography in America. Did the adoption of Keynesian economics during the war time contribute to a continued “military Keynesianism” during the Cold War that followed? If Roosevelt had adopted the Keynesian viewpoint during a time of peace, would the world have been spared the military expenditures that sustained economic growth well into the late 1980’s? While it is not explicitly stated, it seems correct to state that Adelstein believes that much of the political conflicts between capitalism and communism could have been avoided. This is to suggest an economic basis for war and the continuing antagonisms that have existed until the collapse of the Soviet Union. In this “alternative” revisionists viewpoint, the true ideology of Keynesian economics was lost at the start of World War II. From this perspective, Skidelsky’s questions about the usefulness of Keynesian economics are nullified. The potential for the macroeconomics of peace were replaced by the macroeconomics of war with start of World War II. This distortion of Keynesian economics is thus the cause of the problems that Skidelsky illuminates.

While the argument is provocative, several problems with this “alternative” position come to mind. The first is of course the development of the Atomic Bomb and the ensuing Cold War. If Adelstein’s interpretation of “military Keynesianism” is correct, the cold war could have been avoided and the political antagonism between capitalism and communism would have been avoided. This of course seems doubtful as an effective understanding of political relations following World War II. The ideological clash between capitalist systems and communist systems continue to this day even with the collapse of the Soviet Union. Each system of economic control has produced sectors of population where the notion of equality and social improvement have not been realized. In this sense, the original question raised by Skidelsky becomes relevant once again. Equally, and probably more important, the ramifications of the collapse of the Soviet Union has yet to be played out in history. Will Russia become a capitalist state in the sense that America has? Or will a new form of economic ideology emerge from this ongoing political event?

A second problem with Adelstein’s interpretation has to do with international dependency of commerce. As competing markets have developed around the world, the United States economy has become increasingly dependent upon and connected to the economic repercussions in other countries. While Keynes believed that the same role that the government plays in domestic economics could be applied in international economics, the historical fact remains that America nor any other country can claim a leadership role that would make Keynesian economics work. Resistance to economic imperialism is as real as resistance to ideological imperialism. Equally, the idea that an “impartial elite” who determines governmental expenditures, important in the Keynesian economic ideology, would somehow be acceptable to all nationalities is simplistic at best.

A third problem deals with the revisionist historiography. While the article presents some provoking thoughts on “military Keynesianism,” just how valuable is this “alternative interpretation”in understanding historical events? The fact that Roosevelt did not adopt a Keynesian position in the 1930’s is not generally contested. One must ask then, what value does the historian place in the evaluation of historical events by “attempting to understand what did happen by asking what did not?” To present a scenario that has not happened in history amounts to pure speculation and probably is more philosophical in nature than historical. If this is the case, then perhaps it has redeeming value to philosophical speculation, a predominate problem with intellectual history, but has limited value for a productive understanding of recorded history.

Ideology will always be a major consideration in understanding how historical events have unfolded. However, it is how ideology is expressed and modified in the historical context that is of importance to the historian. In this study, one could argue effectively that “military Keynesianism” provided an effective economic strategy that allowed capitalism, and the corollary ideas of freedom and equality, to prosper over an communist economic system that has now been largely abandoned by the world’s nations. In many respects, however, it seems we are back to Skidelsky’s original predicament. Gvien the economic hardship that abounds in many areas of the world, the question still remains, will capitalism be abandoned for a more novel or equitable system in the future? Only time will answer that question.

HOME    

Education           Economics          History

 © CopyRight 2002 Scott R. Simpson