Privatisation
and Deregulation
Privatisation is a supply side approach to bringing about increases in economic growth. Supply side economics is the application of microeconomic policies intended to increase the overall supply of goods and services. By increasing the efficiency of the factor inputs in the production process output should increase. This should have the effect of shifting aggregate supply to the right and increasing the potential level of output as shown in the diagram below.
Arguments in
favour of Privatisation:
Economists offer several arguments in favour of transferring government run firms to the private sector:
Arguments
against Privatisation:
The process of privatisation and deregulation is intended to increase the level of competition. However, this may not happen for a number of reasons:
Privatisation
Process in Pakistan
History and
evolution of privatisation in Pakistan:
The concept of privatisation is not new to the policy makers of this country. It may be traced as back as in 50s, when Pakistan Industrial Development Corporation (PIDC) was established in 1952 to boost up the industrial development in the country. This premier Corporation established over 50 industrial undertakings in the length and breadth of the country and after their successful operation and management, these units were transferred from the public to the private sector. The tide of nationalisation, which swept the whole economy in the first half of 70s, was reversed in 1977. The privatisation of State Owned Enterprises (SOE) became an important instrument of economic policy of the government in late 80s. However, it was in 1991 that privatisation process in Pakistan became effective.
In this topic, we will limit our discussion only to the privatisation process post-1991. In 1990-91, the new government declared privatisation as its primary economic policy objective. The agenda of privatisation announced by the Government covered a wide spectrum of fields like industries, banks, development finance institutions, telecommunications and infrastructure facilities. The government announced the creation of a Privatisation Commission on 22nd January, 1991 to implement the disinvestment programme within the shortest possible time. The birth of Privatisation Commission institutionalised privatisation efforts in Pakistan.
While providing a legal cover to the privatisation process, the government at the same time also moved to protect the interests of the stakeholders, of which labour was given primary importance. A separate Inter-Ministerial Committee was constituted to deal with the labour employed in the SOEs and safeguard their rights. The Committee negotiated a package of incentives for labour employed in these enterprises with the representatives of workers. The agreement with labour was executed on October 15, 1991. The agreement has provided the basic parameters to safeguard the interests of labour and include minimum one year service guarantee after privatisation, reservation of 10% shares for the labour, opportunity to the employees to purchase the unit by putting competitive bid and several other concessions to the workers. It also provided a scheme of Golden Hand Shake (GHS) and Voluntary Separation Scheme (VSS) for the workers and officers of the public sector undertakings.
Overall results of the privatisation process in Pakistan are mixed. In certain sectors like power generation, financial institutions, cement and automobile the performance of the privatised units is satisfactory and the new management have succeeded in improving the quality of product and service as well as financial health of the units. The workers have also benefited in terms of higher salaries and better working conditions. In other sectors like edible oil and roti plants privatisation has not been very successful.
During January 1991
to June 2003 the Commission completed 132 transactions for Rs 101 billion.
During the financial year 2003-2004, the
Commission has successfully completed privatisation of 8 transactions including
privatisation of Habib Bank Limited, AC Cement Rohri, Thatta Cement Limited,
Kohinoor Oil Mills, and Capital Market Transactions (OGDCL, SSGC, POL, ARL, DG
Khan Cement and NBP). The total sale proceeds realized during the year amounted
to Rs.33.3 billion. Out of the sale
proceeds received during the year, the Commission has remitted Rs.11.2 billion
to the Government of Pakistan for debt retirement and poverty alleviation
program. The Commission during
period from July 2004 to April 25, 2005 has realized Rs. 33.8 billion from sale
of GOP shares in PIA, PPL, KAPCO, Falleti’s Hotel and 10% additional
shares of Kohat Cement, Dandot Cement Ltd. By 25th April 2005, the Government of
Pakistan had completed or approved 147 transactions at gross proceeds of Rs 168
billion. Some of the major
transactions recently completed are:
Sale of 51% of GOP stake in Habib Bank Limited for Rs. 22.4 billion
51% shares of United Bank Limited sold in October, 2002. Payment of Rs.1.85 billion received.
75% shares of MCB Bank (formerly Muslim Commercial Bank) were sold in April, 1991 for Rs.2.42 billion. Remaining shares were divested during the years 2001 and 2002 for proceeds of Rs.1.29 billion.
Divestment of approx. 23% shares of National Bank of Pakistan through IPO/POs during the years 2001 to 2003.
70% shares of Bank Al-Falah (formerly Habib Credit & Exchange Bank) were sold in July, 1997 for Rs.1.63 billion. 2% shares were meant for the HCEBL employees 28% shares sold in block for Rs.1.2 billion.
Allied Bank Limited was privatised in 1991 with 51% shares being sold to the ABL employees.
Banker’s Equity Limited was privatised in June, 1996 with 26% shares for proceeds of Rs.618.7 million.
Sale of 5% ordinary shares of Oil & Gas Development Company Limited (OGDCL) through Capital Market for Rs. 6.8 billion.
Sale of Thatta Cement for Rs. 794 million
Sale of 10% shares of Sui Southern Gas Limited (SSGCL) for Rs. 1.7 billion through Capital Market
Sale of shares of Kohinoor Oil Mills Limited for Rs. 81 million
Sale of 6% shares of Pakistan International Airlines (PIA) for Rs. 1.3 billion through Capital Market
Sale of 15% shares of Pakistan Petroleum Limited (PPL) through Capital Market for Rs. 5.7 billion
Sale of 20% shares of Kot Addu Power Company (KAPCO) through Capital Market for Rs. 5.3 billion
Number
of privatised transactions (1991
– April 25, 2005) |
||
Sector |
No.
of Transactions |
Amount (Rs.
In million) |
Banking |
7 |
41,023 |
Capital
Market Transaction |
17 |
31,700 |
Energy |
13 |
41,144 |
Telecom |
2 |
30,558 |
Automobile |
7 |
1,102 |
Cement |
14 |
8,681 |
Chemical
/ Fertilizer |
18 |
10,204 |
Engineering |
7 |
183 |
Ghee
Mills |
22 |
837 |
Rice
/ Roti Plants |
23 |
326 |
Textile |
2 |
|
Newspapers |
5 |
270 |
Tourism |
4 |
1,805 |
Others |
6 |
160 |
Total |
147 |
168,080 |
Some Major Forthcoming
Transactions:
Privatisation
Commission had invited Expressions of Interest (EOIs) from qualified utility
operators and strategic and financial investors in September 2003 for sale of up
to 73% shares of KESC, with management control.
Four parties submitted EOIs and were evaluated by the Commission.
Three parties were pre-qualified and invited to sign the Confidentiality
Agreement and undertake due diligence prior to bidding.
The bidding for KESC was held on February 4, 2005. Two Parties i.e. Hasan
Associate Consortium and Kanooz al Watan (Saudi Arabia) participated in the bid.
Kanwooz Al Watan submitted the
highest bid of Rs. 20.24 billion.
Expected
Transactions during the Year 2005 |
|
Name of SOEs / transactions |
Type of sale envisaged |
Oil and
Gas: |
|
Pakistan
State Oil (PSO) |
51%
shares alongwith management control |
Banking
and Finance: |
|
National
Investment Trust (NIT) |
Sale
of management rights |
Investment
Corp. of Pakistan (ICP) |
Strategic
sale |
Power: |
|
Faisalabad
Electric Supply Co (FESCO) |
56%
shares alongwith management control |
Genco
1 (Jamshoro) |
51%
shares alongwith management control |
Industry
and Real Estate: |
|
Javedan
Cement Company Ltd. |
96.34%
shares alongwith management control |
Mustehkum
Cement Ltd. |
85.29%
shares alongwith management control |
Bolan
Textile Mills |
Machinery
sale |
Lasbella
Textile Mills |
Machinery
sale |
Malam
Jabba |
Not
yet determined |
Pak-American
Fertilizer Ltd. |
94.3%
shares alongwith management control |
National
Construction Ltd. (NCL) |
Not
yet determined |
Morafco
Industries Faisalabad |
Not
yet determined |
Republic
Motors Ltd. |
Not
yet determined |
Lyallpur
Chemical |
Not
yet determined |
Hazara
Phosphate |
Not
yet determined |
Tomato
Paste Plant |
Asset
sale |
Printing
Corporation of Pakistan Pvt. Ltd. |
Not
yet determined |
Karachi
Shipyard and Engineering Works Ltd. |
|
Pakistan
Steel Mills Corporation |
Not
yet determined |
Dr. Ishrat Husain, the Governor of State Bank of Pakistan, in his speech at the Overseas Universities Alumni Club and the 21st Century Business & Economics Club on August 12th 2005, gives the exact answer to the questions arising about the rationale for privatisation in Pakistan. According to him, two decades later, after the nationalization of 1970s, it turned out that nationalization was not only unrealistic and flawed but the consequences were exactly opposite to what the intentions were. The collapse of the Soviet Union and the bankruptcy of the socialist model eroded the ideological underpinning of this strategy and the actual results on the ground in Pakistan and almost all the developing countries shattered the ideal and utopian dreams of the proponents of this philosophy. Pakistan’s public enterprises including banks became a drain on the country’s finances through continuous haemorrhaging and leakages and a drag on the economic growth impulses. The poor instead of benefiting were actually worse off as almost Rs.100 billion a year were spent out of the budget annually on plugging the losses of these corporations, banks and other enterprises. These public enterprises became the conduit for employing thousands of supporters of political parties that assumed power in the country in rapid succession and a source of patronage, perks and privileges for the ministers and the favoured bureaucrats appointed to manage these enterprises. These employees and managers had neither the managerial expertise nor technical competence to carry out the job. Instead of providing goods & services to the common citizens at competitive prices efficiently, the public enterprises turned into avenues for loot and plunder, inefficient provision of services and production of shoddy goods.
In the past, private entrepreneurs in Pakistan did not make ‘profits’ in the real economic sense by earning a return on their investment in a competitive world. On the contrary, they earned ‘rents’ through the maze of permits, licences, preferred credit by the banks, subsidies, privileges, concessions and specific SROs granted to few favoured firms. Naturally when one sees people becoming rich not through the dint of their hard work and enterprise but by manipulation, or bypassing the established rules and laws, we should not be surprised to see the venom against the so called ‘private profits’.
The policy reforms introduced in Pakistan in 1991 has three key essentials – (i) Liberalisation, (ii) Deregulation, and (iii) Privatisation. But unfortunately, Pakistan could not follow through these reforms in a continuous and consistent manner despite the fact that both Benazir and Nawaz Sharif governments were fully committed to these reforms. For example, 12% shares of PTCL were first sold to the general public in 1993-94 and it has been on the privatisation agenda of every successive government since then.
According to a popular view in Pakistan it is okay to sell the loss making enterprises but retain the profit making entities such as PTCL and PSO in the public sector. The main economic logic behind this divestiture is that it will promote efficient allocation of scarce resources, optimal utilization of resources, making sound, timely and market responsive investment choices, winning and retaining customer’s loyalty through better service standards and lower product prices or user charges and contributing to the expansion of the economy through taxes, dividends etc. The basic reason for privatising these enterprises is that the government should not be in the business of running businesses but regulating businesses. The role of the government should be that of a neutral umpire, who lays down the ground rules for businesses to operate and compete, to monitor and enforce these rules, to penalize those found guilty of contraventions and to adjudicate disputes between the competing business firms. If the government owned firm itself, there is a strong conflict of interest and the other competitors lose confidence in the neutrality of the umpire. Under these circumstances, the market becomes chaotic, disorderly and unruly as there is no neutral ‘person’ to monitor and enforce the rules. The economy thus pays a heavy price for this loss of the market mechanism in the production, sale and distribution of goods and services. The present controversy between the PIA and private airlines is a manifestation of this tendency. The same argument can be applied in case of PTCL. If the Government had continued to own and manage PTCL, the private sector competing firms would have felt that they would always remain at a disadvantage in relation to the PTCL. The constant fear that the government’s coercive powers and full force of policy making ability would always be used to safeguard and enhance the interests of PTCL. This would have kept the private firms away from investment in the fixed telephone or wireless loop segments.
The fears about employment losses in the industry as a result of privatisation are also, by and large, unfounded. The example of the banking industry privatisation controverts those who claim that privatisation means jobs are lost. In 1997 when the restructuring, down-sizing and privatisation of the nationalized commercial banks picked up speed there were 105,000 employees working in the financial sector. After privatisation was completed, the banking industry has expanded and the work force has expanded to 114,000. It is true that the pattern of employment has changed and more productive and skilled workers have been taken in at the expense of low skilled or unskilled.
Telecom sector has already generated, after deregulation, hundreds of thousands of new jobs through public call offices, calling cards and pre-paid card companies, Internet Service Providers, mobile phone companies, broad band services, and other value added services under the private sector. As the penetration ratios in Pakistan are still quite low, there is going to be a large expansion in the telecom sector. Industry estimates that 100,000 new jobs will be added during next 3 – 5 years.
Conclusion:
Privatisation contributes to economic growth through productivity gains, efficient utilization of resources, better governance and expansion in output and employment. Profit making enterprises under the public sector may be making profits due to the unique market structure such as monopoly or other privileges or concessions conferred upon them by the government but it does so at the expense of the consumer who has to pay higher than market price for the product or the services. The ordinary consumer gets a benefit only through competition among private sector firms in form of lower prices and better services as has been demonstrated in the cases of banking, telecommunications and, more recently, air travel.
In a deregulated market environment, public ownership becomes a serious constraint as the rule – bound procedures and the rigidity in the structure do not allow public sector companies the flexibility to respond promptly to dynamic market conditions. Furthermore, the government’s role as a regulator and neutral umpire becomes questionable once it is itself a participant in the game through its own company. This stifles competition and subverts expansion and growth by the private sector companies.