Navigation
Papers by Melberg
Elster Page
Ph.D work

About this web
Why?
Who am I?
Recommended
Statistics
Mail me
Subscribe
Search papers
List of titles only
Categorised titles

General Themes
Ph.D. in progress
Economics
Russia
Political Theory
Statistics/Econometrics
Various papers

The Questions
Ph.D Work
Introduction
Cost-Benefit
Statistical Problems
Social Interaction
Centralization vs. Decentralization

Economics
Define economics!
Models, Formalism
Fluctuations, Crisis
Psychology

Statistics
Econometrics

Review of textbooks

Belief formation
Inifinite regress
Rationality

Russia
Collapse of Communism
Political Culture
Reviews

Political Science
State Intervention
Justice/Rights/Paternalism
Nationalism/Ethnic Violence

Various
Yearly reviews

Philosophy
Explanation=?
Methodology

 

[Note for bibliographic reference: Melberg, Hans O. (1997), Lessons from History, http://www.oocities.org/hmelberg/papers/970818.htm]

 

[Note: This is a revised version of a lecture I gave at the Red Cross Nordic United World College, 31. July, 1997. Thus, the papers has a more oral style than I otherwise would have used if I had been writing this paper for publication. In this version, I tried to include some of the complexities that I had to leave out in the original lecture - which was intended for students who had just finished high-school. However, there are still many arguments which may appear simplistic. For a more in-depth treatment of the topics, I will refer the reader to my reviews of the books mentioned towards the end.]

Lessons from History
The collapse of the Soviet Union and the end of the Cold War

by Hans O. Melberg


Introduction
The title of the topic I was given was "EU-Russian relations, the Baltic, China after Deng, and lessons from history." Obviously, this topic is too large to cover in 45 minutes, so I shall have to focus on some selected issues. I will choose to focus on the last part of the topic - lessons from history.

To be concrete, what kind of lessons, if any, can we draw from the collapse of Communism in the Soviet Union, and the following end of the Cold War? In order to answer this question, I shall use the frame provided by the figure below:

Fig. 1: Can the end of Communism and the Cold War can provide answers
to the four set of questions below?

		Economic				Political
Domestic	What kind of economic system is best?	What kind of political system is best
		Capitalism vs. Socialism		Democracy vs. Authoritarianism

International	How to organize international trade?	How to organize state-state relations?
		Free vs. Managed trade			Realpolitik vs. "Idealpolitik"

Before I go on to discuss these four questions, we need to reflect a little on whether it is possible to learn something from history at all.

Can we learn from history?
When faced with a question like "Should we have free or managed trade?" it seems obvious that we need to go to history to find answers. By looking at the history of different countries with different policies (at different times), we can examine whether free trade created economic growth or not. If we find a historical (positive) correlation between free trade and economic growth, some might say that history has taught us that free trade is better than managed trade.

Unfortunately, it is not that easy. In a previous essay, I presented a long list of problems associated with the use of historical correlations as evidence for or against a statement (see, Against Correlation). For example, there might be a third variable which causes free trade and economic growth to be correlated, even if the two are not causally related. Imagine, for the sake or argument, that free trade really is bad, or neutral, for economic growth, but that free trade policies are more likely to be implemented by rulers who otherwise tend to implement good economic policies. This would mean that free trade and economic growth were positively correlated, but it would be wrong to infer that free trade causes economic growth. In fact, the opposite would be the case, but this effect is hidden by the third variable. Because of this, and other problems, we should be careful with the use of history (in the sense of correlation between variables) to prove arguments.

Being careful, of course, does not imply that statistical evidence from history is worthless. It is possible to use more sophisticated statistical techniques to reduce the danger of ignoring a third variable (for instance, by differencing the data). It is also possible to conduct experiments to isolate the effects of the different variables. Hence, we should not arrive at the nihilistic conclusion that quantitative research is worthless, only that there are degrees of uncertainty attached to all our conclusions.

Are there any alternatives to the use of historical correlations when we want to draw lessons from history? One alternative to searching for historical correlations to justify arguments, would be to work deductively to show exactly how two variables are related - in this case, the mechanisms linking fee trade and economic growth. These are two very different approaches. The first, which we may call induction, justified an argument by saying that history showed a pattern - a correlation - between the two variables. The second approach aims to validate an argument by showing why we find a relationship between the two variables. However, even the second approach needs history to furnish some initial premises before the deductive machinery can be put to effect. For instance, traditional economics often works deductively from the premise that individuals are rational and selfish. This premise, in turn, must be justified by appealing to history. Thus, there is an alternative to working only with correlation, but also this approach requires input from history.

These were some theoretical reflections on the possibility of learning from history. In sum, while I do believe history is important as a source of evidence for or against theories and arguments, I also believe there often is a great deal of uncertainty attached to the conclusions when we use historical evidence. There are (often) too many variables at work, and our statistical tools are not powerful enough to provide the certainty we desire. However, this does not imply that the study of history is a waste. There are many reasons to study history, except for the argument that we should "learn" from history. For instance, historical knowledge is pleasing in itself, in the same way as listening to music is inherently pleasing. Moreover, studying history may be important for reasons related to identity - to satisfy a desire to know our roots. Finally, history is important in that it makes us aware that there is sometimes nothing inherently "natural", inevitable or unavoidable about certain norms and institutions. Looking to other historical epochs we learn that situations change (often fast and in seemingly unpredictable ways), and that people are able to live under a wide range of norms and arrangements. Thus, knowledge of history often undermines the often used "this is the way it has always been" as an argument for status quo.

What kind of economic system is best?
Capitalism vs. Socialism
Some, like Francis Fukuyama, argue that the collapse of Communism in the Soviet Union provided the ultimate answer to what kind of economic system that is best. In short, capitalism (private ownership and free price setting) won over socialism (public ownership and central planning). The lesson seems obvious, but as always there are complexities which should make us less than certain.

To say that "capitalism won" is not a very detailed lesson since there are many different shades of capitalism. Norway is a capitalist country, as is Hong Kong, but the degree of state intervention in the economy differs greatly from Norway to Hong Kong. Hence, to say that Capitalism won does not give us a detailed answer to the correct level of state intervention in the economy.

More theoretically, the inference from "100% state intervention is bad" to the argument that "40% state intervention is worse than 30%" is false (because the relationship is not linear). Or, to use an analogy: Cutting off your head is bad, but this does not imply that shaving is worse than no shaving. Or: 100% vodka is bad, but this does not imply that 10% vodka is worse than 5%.

To be a bit more concrete, some kinds of state intervention is necessary to make capitalism work. Consider, for instance, the Polaroid camera. It took quite a lot of resources (research) to develop the technology behind these cameras. In an economy with absolutely no state intervention, another company could simply steal (re-engineering) this technology, thus avoiding the research costs. If this kind of stealing had been possible, less resources would be dedicated to research: Why do research when you do not benefit from them and other companies simply steal your inventions? This, in turn, is not good for economic efficiency. Hence, the state must intervene - to enforce copyright and patent rights - in order to make capitalism efficient. This is one kind of "good" state intervention.

Lastly, some would argue that Capitalism did not win over Socialism in general. Rather, capitalism won over one particular type of socialism which, moreover, ran into a series of unfortunate accidents (Stalin, World War II). I disagree with this argument. Maybe there exists more democratic types of socialism which does not include central planning, but I remain sceptical (see John Roemer for an argument to this effect, and my review of the book for some counter-arguments).

To sum up. History has taught us that close to 100% state ownership and central planning tends to produce inefficiencies. However, this does not imply that there should be no state intervention, nor does it give us the "correct" level of state intervention.

What kind of political system is best?
Democracy vs. Authoritarianism

One might argue that this question is a bit obvious. "Of course democracy is best," most people would respond. Moreover, they would say that history proves this: If we divide the world into democratic and non-democratic countries we find that democracies are wealthy, relative stable, and peace loving. Hence, of course democracy is best!

First, however obvious the issue seems today, the answer was not obvious fifty years ago. Democracies appeared weak (1930s), while fascism, embodied in Mussolini and Hitler, was strong. If we today think democracy is obviously superior, this too must count as a lessons from history - first the defeat of fascism in World War II, and later the collapse of Communism in the Cold War. Both events discredited non-democratic ways of government, and made people believe that democracy was the best way of organizing state-individual relations.

Still, even the seemingly obvious answer "history shows that democracy is better than authoritarianism" is not very satisfactory. We do not know exactly what democracy is, and when we try to define it we encounter several problems. A concrete example may help: Assume that democracy means rule by majority decisions in free elections. Now, as a though experiment imagine that three persons are going to divide a cake. It is perfectly possible that a democratic way of dividing this cake would produce the result that one person gets nothing, while the two others get half each. If people are selfish, then two people would vote for this alternative (those two who benefit), and this constitutes a majority [note: there are some problems here relating to the stability of this solution if we allow several rounds of bargaining before the vote]. This "democratic" way of dividing the cake does not appear intuitively appealing, and as such it illustrates a problem with democracies - the tyranny of majorities.

If we make a swift change from the world of cakes, to the real world, we find that the problem described above is very much alive. Obviously minorities like the Sami and the Roma people may experience that the majority imposes their own will on them using "democratic" decisions. Less obviously, groups - such as smokers - may suffer under the same flaw in democracy when the majority outlaws smoking in private places (like restaurants).

Are there any solutions to the cake problem? One possible answer, is constitutional provisions guaranteeing the individual a private sphere which the state - or the majority - is not allowed to interfere with. Of course, this is not a perfect solution; we might disagree on what rights to include, on the interpretation of the constitutional articles, and, lastly, the court does not have an army to protect its ruling against a political leadership determined to ignore the court. Thus, constitutions may reduce, but not solve the problem of the tyranny of the majority.

Yet another problem with democracy, concerns who is allowed to vote. In most democracies the only requirement is age, sanity and citizenship. This may seems perfectly fair, but consider the situation in Latvia and Estonia. In these two states there are large Russian minorities which are not citizens of the states - only residents. Accordingly, the Russians do not have the right to vote in these countries. Is this fair? Is it democratic? It is easy for foreigners to say that this is unfair discrimination, but would you give the right to vote to the people from a nation which occupied your country for fifty years? To be concrete, if you are Norwegian, would you accept that the Germans who occupied Norway during World War II should be given citizenship and the right to vote after the war if they wanted to stay? Maybe the situation is somewhat different - the Russian occupation of the Baltic states lasted longer and many Russians who came were not occupying soldiers, but regular workers - but the question nevertheless show that the issue of who should be allowed to vote does not have an obvious solution.

Has history taught us that democracy is better than authoritarianism? Maybe, but history has not given us detailed lessons in exactly what for of democracy is best, not is democracy perfect. In the end, I guess, I agree with Churchill that democracy wins because there are no better alternatives! Certainly not authoritarianism!

How to organize international trade?
Free vs. Managed trade

On the third topic, the organization of international trade, I am of the opinion that both history and theory shows that free trade is almost always good. Historically it seems true that free trade has generated economic growth and managed trade has produced lower rates of economic growth (i.e. a correlation); Witness, for example the failure of those developing countries which tried to protect their industries in order to increase economic growth (the infant industry argument). Theoretically, it seems obvious that if each country produce most of what they are best at, the overall welfare of everybody is increased. It does not make sense for Norway to be self-sufficient in the production of bananas!

However, many people continue to be against free trade, and many believe that free trade decreases their welfare. To explain this, I will use a concrete example: Agriculture. Assume you live in a country, like Lithuania, with a rather large agricultural sector. Assume, also, that in order to protect the farmers from cheaper imported agricultural products, the government has imposed a tariff on foreign foodstuff. Is this good or bad? The good effects are highly concentrated - the farmers keep their jobs. However, the bad effects should also be counted. The bad effect of the tariff, is that many people must pay a little more for the food than they would if they could buy imported food. Or, to put it in another way, the benefit of free trade would be that a lot of people would get cheaper food; while the cost is that some farmers would loose their job or, at least, receive less income. It is important to note that the benefit of free trade is widely dispersed - a lot of people get a little cheaper food. In contrast, the cost of free trade is highly visible and concentrated - whole farm communities may go bankrupt.

Now, the question was whether the government should continue to impose a tariff on imported foodstuff. It can be proved mathematically that the total amount of money gained by free trade is larger than the total sum lost by the farmers, but in itself this does not prove that free trade is best (to do so we also need to engage in inter-personal comparison of utility.). However, one should not one thing: I said that one cost of free trade was that some farmers would loose their jobs. However, what if these farmers could get new jobs? If so, it seems that the cost of free trade disappear, and there are (almost) only benefits (almost because the adjustment period may be painful). How can I be so confident that the farmers will get new jobs? Remember that free trade implied that a lot of people would get cheaper food. Hence, when they have to spend less of their income on food, they can spend more on other things. And, when people spend more on other products, new jobs are created in these sectors. In short, the cost of free trade is mainly temporary: People will, over time, get new jobs!

Of course, I do not know how long the adjustment period is - and this is a problem. You simply cannot take a Polish farmer and turn him into a computer programmer. However, it is possible that the son of the farmer can become a computer-programmer. So, in some instances the transition period might be relatively long, and the social costs are quite high. And, even temporary costs are real costs!

Lastly, I have encountered one counter-argument to the discussions above: What if the increased real income generated by free trade is used on imported goods. If so, then it will not generate jobs in your country. The money is spent on foreign goods, produced by foreign workers. Is this argument sound?

No! It is a myth that import is "bad", and that export" is good. What could be better than receiving real goods in exchange for paper-money (i.e. import)! Remember, in itself the paper is not valuable! The paper is only valuable since it can buy goods, and your currency can only buy goods in your country. [The belief that money in itself is valuable could be explained by cognitive mechanisms, a mechanism which in turn would explain why people think that "import" is bad and "export" is good.] Of course, it is not only a piece of a paper, but consider what the foreigners can do with the money they receive. They can either spend the money in your own country or exchange the money into some other currency (ignoring the "doing nothing" option which is unlikely). If they spend the money on goods in your country, the "return" the profit they "stole", and you are no worse off - in fact, you are better off: more employment is generated. What happens if the firms exchange the money - are you worse off? No, in this case the money is also "returned" to the home-economy. (True, in this case you pay to get the currency back [which in itself is no goal], but the very fact that the exchange is voluntary indicate that it benefits both parties - both the seller and the buyer of the currencies). In short, buying imported goods does not imply that your country "loose" - the money is not worth anything in itself, and will in any case be "returned" to your economy - either directly (foreigners buying goods) or indirectly (exchange).

It is time to end this section. I started by arguing that free trade is almost always good. I hope to have showed that this argument is justified, both by looking at historical evidence, and by more theoretical considerations. True, there are some exceptions, but these are not important enough to make a general argument against free trade (for more on this - both the benefits of free trade and the exceptions, see Krugman).

How to organize state-state relations?
Realpolitik vs. "Idealpolitik"

If you were the foreign minister of your country, what kind of principles would you use to formulate a foreign policy? Does history teach us what kind of foreign policy that is best? To make the choice more stark, I shall consider two such principles - what one might call "realpolitik" (pursuing national interests) vs. "idealpolitik" (pursuing ideals like justice). As an illustration of the two, remember the difference in the US reaction in Kuwait and Bosnia. Kuwait had oil, which in turn meant that large US interests were at stake. Bosnia had no oil, which implied that the interests of the US were less clear. Hence, realpolitik dictated that Kuwait should be saved, but not Bosnia. [To be sure, there were other differences too, such as the terrain: A large scale invasion to save Bosnia would be a nightmare because of the mountains, unlike the flat desert in Kuwait].

What does history teach us about the choice between realpolitik and idealpolitik? Let me first point to a few lessons that I think history provides, before I return to the question of realpolitik vs. idealpolitik. First, I think history shows that "vacuums" tend to create conflict. In a world of competition for influence, the blocks will compete for the countries that are outside - and this competition generates tension. Second, history shows that tension can arise out of misunderstandings, and that good lines of communication is one way of preventing this. For example, The Economist recently reported that Argentina and Chile had agreed to standardize the rules concerning defense expenditure accounting. Previously, none of the countries knew how much the other was spending on defense since many of the costs were hidden outside the defense budget. This situation led to a spiral of increasing expenditure (justified by the argument that "they might be spending more than us ...), and mutual suspicion. With clear lines of communication - the standardized accounting rules - this source of tension is reduced. Third, history shows that over-extension is a constant danger. By over-extension I mean a country trying to pursue too many goals compared to the resources they are willing to spend (or have!) to achieve these goals.

Let me now use these "lessons" in the choice between realpolitik and idealpolitik, and - once again - for sake of argument I want to use NATO expansion as an example.

The idealist position is that every country has the right to determine whatever alliances they want to belong to. On this view it is not Russia's objections to NATO expansion should not be given much weight, and the Baltic countries should be admitted. The problem with this point of view, is that it might lead to over-extension. There are simply too many countries that needs to be rescued compared to the resources we have, or the resources we are willing to spend. Consider, for example, the bloody experience of Somalia, in which US and Western troops intervened mainly for "ideal" reasons [to restore order and protect the aid], but it turned out that they were not willing to let their own soldiers die for this cause.

Does this mean that "realpolitik" is a better option? Let us examine what adherents of "realpolitik" would say about NATO expansion. Some might argue that vacuums are bad, so NATO should expand, also into the Baltic states. However, some might worry about this leading to over-extension. Others, in turn, might be willing to sacrifice the rights of some countries, to please Russia, thus admitting some countries into NATO, while agreeing with Russia that some countries - like the Baltic countries - should not be allowed into NATO. This position may seem cynical - and it is - but this is the kind of foreign policy you get when you try to balance the god and bad consequences, not taking the idealist position that actions should be guided by "right and wrong" regardless of consequences.

I cannot say that I have a clear-cut answer to the choice between realpolitik and idealpolitik. In fact, I think the difference is exaggerated. Even an "ideal-politician" might agree that we should avoid over-extension, but still pursue as many ideals as we can within these limits - such as trying to promote democracy in non-democratic states. Also, even "real-politicians" have ideals - the policy of containment against Communism (Keenan) was based on the idea that "our" system (democracy, capitalism) was better than "theirs" (communism, central planning).

Linking the four questions
So far I have treated the four questions as isolated issues, but clearly the choice of economic system is related to the choice of political system - there are few dictatorships that practice free trade and a free market economy! Hence, before I end I want to discuss a few of the possible linkages between the four choices.

Consider first how intervention in free-trade might affect the political system. Assume, for instance, that the government introduces a tariff on cigarettes. This, in turn, will most probably lead to smuggling. Increased smuggling might lead to calls for a strengthening of the powers of the police to catch the smugglers. This leads to a slippery slope in which the private sphere is gradually decreased as the state tries to combat smuggling i.e. intervention in trade leads to a more authoritarian political system. Of course, this trend should not be exaggerated - there are also many other causal variables at work preventing the slide into totalitarianism even if you introduce a tariff on cigarettes. My point, however, was to simply give one example of how the answer to the trade question affects the choice between political systems.

A better example, maybe, of a link is the choice between the economic and the political system within a country. If you choose capitalism, history shows that it seems difficult to prevent the desire for democracy (see, for example, South Korea, China and other countries in Asia). In a free economy, the government cannot prevent the sale of photocopiers, computers, television, phones and other equipment which makes the organization of an opposition easier. Moreover, with increasing levels of education, people are not as easily fooled into servility. Educated people will demand a say in policy-formation, and they will not be silenced by the argument that "you stupid peasants know nothing about how to govern a country". Thus, free markets tend to develop demands for democracy.

Conclusion
I have touched on a large number of topics - the choice of political system, economic system, foreign policy, and international trade. In all these areas, I believe history provides us with broad lessons, but once we enter into the details history seldom gives us precise answers. For instance, the collapse of the Soviet Union demonstrated the inefficiency of 100% state intervention, but it does not give us the answer to the question of exactly what level of state-intervention is optimal. Maybe, as I tried to say in the introduction, there are simply too many variables at work to ever find reliable and detailed answers to all out question. If so, we must base the choice of policies not so much on "lessons from history" as out moral intuition of what is right and wrong (See Jon Elster's article The Possibility of Rational Politics for more on this).



Here is a copy of the hand-out I gave to the participants, including a list of sources used in the preparation of this lecture

Lessons from the end of the Cold War 
for the current situation
by Hans O. Melberg (http://www.oocities.org/hmelberg/index.htm)
* Structure: 
The question is whether the end of Cold War can provide answers to the four set of questions below.
		Economic					Political
Domestic	What kind of economic system is best?	What kind of political system is best
		Capitalism vs. Socialism			Democracy vs. Authoritarianism

International	How to organize international trade?	How to organize state-state relations?
		Free vs. Managed trade			Realpolitik vs. "Idealpolitik"

* Some notes that will make sense after the lecture! 
1. Socialism vs. Capitalism
- Even if 100% vodka is bad, this does not imply that 10% vodka is worse than 5% vodka!
- Polaroid cameras, patent rights and state intervention

2. Democracy vs. Authoritarianism
- What is the democratic way of dividing a cake?
- Tyranny of the majority against the minority (Baltics?, or?)

3. Free vs. Managed trade
- Why free trade is almost always good and why governments almost never follow 
free trade policies (Benefits of managed reade are concentrated, costs are dispersed)
- Links between (not) free trade and authoritarianism/democracy (example: China)

4. Realpolitik vs. Idealpolitik
- Kuwait vs. Bosnia (Somalia?)
- NATO expansion? EU expansion? OSCE? Russia-Europe

* Some sources (selcted, not comprehensive)
* The main source of this lecture is my articles and reviews available on the Internet 
(http://www.oocities.org/hmelberg/papers/papers.htm). You will find book reviews of all the books 
mentioned below on that page. Comments and criticism are welcome! My ideas are also 
greatly inspired by Jon Elster (see http://www.oocities.org/hmelberg/elster.htm).

* On the difference between the principles governing Western and Eastern (China, Russia) 
foreign policy, see: Michael Mandelbaum (1997), Westernizing Russia and China, Foreign 
Affairs, vol. 76, no. 3, pp. 81-95

* About the situation of the Russians in the Baltic states: Pål Kolstø, (ed.) (1997), Integration 
and nation-building, forthcoming book (maybe under another title). Also, Richard Rose (1997 
- winter), Rights and Obligations of Individuals in the Baltic States, East European 
Constitutional Review, pp. 35-43

* About NATO expansion: Several articles in ACE (Analysis of Current Events), vol. 9, no. 5, 
1997. See also, The Economist (July 12th-18th) and the next issue (July 19th-25th) for EU 
expansion).

* More generally about the lessons from the collapse of Communism:
- Four "conservative" and controversial books: Zbigniew Brzezinski (1989) The Grand 
Failure: The Birth and Decay of Communism in the Twentieth Century, New York: Charles 
Schribner's Sons; Martin Malia (1994), The Soviet Tragedy: A History of Socialism in Russia, 
1917-1991, New York, The Free Press  (long, more than 500 pages - but comprehensive); 
Richard Pipes (1994, reprinted 1995), Communism: The Vanished Specter, Oslo: 
Scandinavian University Press (very controversial, lists several "lessons" from the collapse); 
Robert Skidelsky (1995), The World After Communism, London: Macmillan (A mix of 
economic and political lessons. Main topic: State intervention)
- One "left-wing" book dealing mainly with the economic lessons from the collapse of 
Communism: John Roemer (1994), A Future for Socialism, Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard 
University Press

* On free trade (and many other economic issues), see Paul Krugman (1994), Peddling 
Prosperity: Economic sense and nonsense ..., London: W.W. Norton (enjoyable!)

[Note for bibliographic reference: Melberg, Hans O. (1997), Lessons from History, http://www.oocities.org/hmelberg/papers/970818.htm]