Navigation
Papers by Melberg
Elster Page
Ph.D work

About this web
Why?
Who am I?
Recommended
Statistics
Mail me
Subscribe
Search papers
List of titles only
Categorised titles

General Themes
Ph.D. in progress
Economics
Russia
Political Theory
Statistics/Econometrics
Various papers

The Questions
Ph.D Work
Introduction
Cost-Benefit
Statistical Problems
Social Interaction
Centralization vs. Decentralization

Economics
Define economics!
Models, Formalism
Fluctuations, Crisis
Psychology

Statistics
Econometrics

Review of textbooks

Belief formation
Inifinite regress
Rationality

Russia
Collapse of Communism
Political Culture
Reviews

Political Science
State Intervention
Justice/Rights/Paternalism
Nationalism/Ethnic Violence

Various
Yearly reviews

Philosophy
Explanation=?
Methodology

 

[Note for bibliographic reference: Melberg, Hans O. (1998), Pay according to need or effort? A starting point for thinking about the value of models in economics , www.oocities.org/hmelberg/papers/980303.htm]

[Note: This paper is not proof-read, and HTML makes it a bit difficult to write "nice" equations]




Pay according to need or effort?
A starting point for thinking about the value of models in economics


by Hans O. Melberg


Introduction
For some time I have intended to examine the value of models in economics and the best way of doing so - I think - is to start by presenting some models. This is what I will do in this review. Based on this model, and a few more, I hope to present a more verbal argument on the general value of models and formal reasoning in a future paper.

In this review I want to examine a model by Amarthya Sen which tries to clarify the problem of pay according to need or effort. The model I will use is a simplified version of Sen's which was developed by K. O. Moene (University of Oslo). Since I want the review to be useful to people with less than perfect mathematical backgrounds, I have included not only the final equations, but also the calculations (and some explanation). Hopefully this is useful for some people.

In order to avoid making this a pure mathematical exercise, I shall try to criticise the model, and more generally reflect on why we build models at all. For instance, in the model I shall use it emerges that - contrary to our immediate intuition - pay according to effort is not socially optimal. This is one criterion for a good model; that it brings out a something we did not know.

The Model
Imagine that your utility depends positively on your income (y) and negatively on your effort (e), so that we have the following utility function for every person (i):

Ui = y - c(e)

Now, assume that some people also care about the utility of other people. Hence:

Vi = Ui + sigma hij Uj

This equations says that person (i) evaluates the "goodness of the world" according to how much utility he himself has (Ui) and the sum of utilities of other people (Uj). The purpose of hij is to allow the person (i) to give more or less weight to different persons (j), specifically that he attaches greater importance to his own utility than another person's utility if h is less than one. To make things simple we shall assume that there are N identical people and that each person gives the same importance to everybody else (the same h for everybody). This implies that:

V = U + h (N -1)^U

Or, in words: a person's evaluation of the situation is given by the size of his own utility and the total sum of the utility of all the other people multiplied by his degree of concern for these people (h). The number of other people is (N-1) and all the other people have the same utility ^U.

Using the information we have so far we are able to construct a measure of a person's degree of "sympathy" for other people. Consider the following equation:

S = [1 + h (N - 1)] / n

If h=0 you do not care about other people, and S=1/n (a small number, no sympathy). If h=1 you think another person's utility is as important as your own utility S=1 (maximum sympathy).

The welfare of society is given by the following utilitarian welfare function:

W = N U, or since we know U (which is the same for all people):

W = N [y - c(e)]

In order to derive some results, we also need a production function:

Q = Q(L, A, v1...vn)

Total production (Q) is a function of the number of efficient labour units used, a fixed factor (like land) and variable capital goods (1...vn).There are three things to note here. First, that L does not simply measure the number of workers, but the number of people multiplied by their effort (e), i.e. the number of efficient labour unit inputs:

L = e N

Second, the existence of A - a factor except for labour and normal capital goods - is important, as we shall see later. Third, we are assuming that the production function has constant returns to scale (CRS), which means that a doubling of all inputs will double the output.

Income per capita is given by total production (at price = 1), minus non-labour costs (C):

y = [Q - C] / N

And costs are the amount of capital goods used multiplied by their price:

C = sigma Pk vk

We have now defined the relationships necessary to compare pay by need and pay by effort. Before we examine this, however, we should find the socially optimal result.

The Social Optimum
To find the social optimum we simply maximize the welfare function. We have:

W = N [ y - c(e)]

We know that y = Q-C / N, so substituting this and rearranging we have:

W = Q - C - N c(e)

To maximize this, we derive with respect to e (we can control effort) and v (since we also control the amount of capital input):

dW/de = NQ'L - N c'(e)

dW/dv = vk - Pk

[For those who do not get this immediately, here is an explanation: Q is a function of L, A and v, and L defined as Ne. This means that we have to derive Q with respect to e implicitly. First we derive L with respect to e (and gets N), second we multiply this by the derivative of Q with respect to L (Q'L). As for the derivative of W with respect to v we note that both Q and C are functions of v.]

In sum, the first order conditions for social optimum are:

Q'L = c'(e)

Pk = vk

The first says that we should choose effort so that the last unit of effort equals the marginal increase in production of using more effort. The second condition simply means that we use less of the more expensive factors of production.

The interesting issue is now to compare the first order conditions for social optimum with the results that emerge if we pay according to effort or need.

Paying according to need
Assume we let each person choose his own level of effort, and that we pay according to need. For the sake of simplicity, I shall simply use the following equation to define "pay by need":

y = [Q - C] / N

In other words, that everybody has the same need and gets paid the same. One could, of course, imagine alternative ways of doing this. For instance, one might define need in terms of number of children, degree of physical handicap or some other characteristic. However, the equation above is by far the easiest to handle mathematically.

Which level of effort would a person choose if he was paid according to need defined in the equation above? To answer this we assume that each person maximize V (satisfaction of extended preferences). Thus:

max V = U + h (N - 1) ^U

max V = [Q - C] / N - c(e) + h (N - 1) [(Q - C) / N - c(ê)]

We take the derivative with respect to e (the person's level of effort):

Q'L / N - c'(e) + h (N - 1) Q'L / N

Setting Q'L outside we get:

Q'L [ (1 + h (N-1) / N ] = c'(e)

Recall the expression for S, we have the following first order condition for optimum when pay is distributed according to need:

Q'L S = c'(e)

If we compare to the first order condition for social optimum, we understand that if there is perfect sympathy, we still have the optimal level of effort. However, if there is less than perfect sympathy (S is less than one) people will supply less effort than is socially optimal. The intuition is simple: The extra income coming from an additional unit of labour is shared with everybody so you do not work as hard as you would if you had received all the extra income from your work. This is a relatively well know conclusion: paying according to need (and not effort) means that people will work less hard. What is not obvious, however, is that the "opposite" - pay according to effort - need not be better.

Pay according to effort
One way of formalizing pay according to effort, is the following:

y = [ (Q - C) / L] e

The equation says that people are paid a share of the profit (revenue - costs) and that the share depends on the level of effort you supply; the more effort, the higher pay.

If we substitute this income equation into the utility function, and the utility function into the extended preferences function, we get the following equation which we want to maximize:

V = [ (Q - C) / L] e - c(e) + h (N - 1) [[ (Q - C) / L] ê - c(ê)]

Derive with respect to e to get:

(Q - C) / L + e [ [Q'L L - (Q - C)] / L2] - c'(e) + h (N - 1) [ [Q'L L - (Q - C)] / L2] ê

Which is the same as

(Q - C) / L + Q'L e/L - (Q - C) / L2 - c'(e) + h (N - 1) [Q'L ê/L - ê (Q - C) / L2]

In equilibrium ê=e and L=Nê so the above can be rearranged as:

Q'L [ 1/N + h (N - 1) / N ] + (Q - C) / L [1 - 1/N - h (N - 1) / N] = c'(e)

If we now define:

b = (Q - C) / Q (average profit per unit produced)

and c = (Q'L/Q) L (elasticity of production with respect to labour)

The we can write:

Q'L [1/N + h (N-1) / N + b/c (1 - S)] = c'(e)

[If you are having problems understanding this, plug in for b and c, and you will find that you get the original equation]. Or, and this is the final result:

Q'L [S + b/c (1 - S)] = c'(e)

What does this equation tell us about the nature of optimum when people are paid according to effort? If S=1 (perfect sympathy) we get Q'L=c'(e) and we are in the social optimum. But, if b>c and S<1 (and A>0) we can see from the equation that people will supply more effort than is socially optimal. In short, under the stated conditions S + b/c (1 - S) is larger than one and we need to supply more effort to make Q'L go down in order to make the left hand side equal to the right hand side.

How do we know that b>c? Remember that we assumed a production function that has constant returns to scale. Mathematically:

Q = Q(L, A, v1...vn)

CRS implies that:

c + eA + sigma ek = 1 (sum of elasticities of factors of production is one)

ek is sigma (Qk vk/Q), but we know that in equilibrium Qk = Pk. Moreover, we know that sigma Pk vk/q is the same as C/Q (since C=sigma Pk vk). Thus, we have:

c + eA + C/Q = 1

Or, to make it more obvious:

1 - C/Q = c + eA

Which is the same as saying:

(Q - C) / Q = c + eA

Remember than b = (Q - C) / Q, we now have:

b = c + eA

This proves that as long as A is not zero then b > c.

Robust mix
So far I have showed how pay according to need results in not enough effort, while pay according to effort gives too much effort (compared to social optimum). An interesting question is how we can find a balance between paying according to need and effort which produces the socially optimum level of effort. It turns out that the answer to this question is not too difficult to find.

Assume that each person receives some of his income according to need (specifically: a), and some of his income in proportion to his effort (1 - a). We have:

y = a (Q - C) / N + (1 - a) [(Q - C) / L] e

Before we start substituting this and maximizing, we should note that this work has essentially been done in the first section of the paper, the only difference being that we now have to include (a) and (1- a). To reduce our workload we simply take the first order conditions we already have and combine them as follows:

a S Q'L + (1 - a) Q'L [ S + b/c (1 - S)] = c'(e)

Rearranging we have the following first order condition:

Q'L [S + (1 - a) (1 - S) b/c] = c'(e)

For this to produce the socially optimal result, we must have:

1 - a = c/b

[Since the condition then becomes Q'L = c'(e)]

So, the problem of whether to pay according to need or effort is reduced to a problem of choosing the size of "a" (how much weight to place on payment according to need relative to effort). Moreover, from the model we understand that the sice of "a" depends on b (the size of value added) and c (the elasticity of production with respect to labour). This sounds intuitively correct, the more sensitive the production is to changes in effort, the more you pay according to effort.

The intuition
Even without the model we might understand that paying according to effort may make people work too much. Imagine that you are one of ten people who live on an island and that the only thing people desire is coconuts. Unfortunately, there are no coconut trees on the island. However, luckily for you a helicopter arrives with 100 000 free coconuts each year. The question then arises: How should these coconuts be distributed? Assume you decide to give most coconuts to the person who digs the deepest whole (roughly equal to pay according to effort). The digging does not serve any productive purposes, it only functions as a way of determining who gets most coconuts. It should be obvious that this is not a very good way of distributing coconuts.

Of course, the real world is more complex: Work usually makes the cake larger and it is difficult to find a good criterion for need (which raise the possibility of manipulation, political problems, rent seeking and so on). Yet, the general intuition still holds: As long as some part of the cake is independent of effort, it would create too strong incentives to work if we distribute the whole cake according to effort.

Criticism
I find it difficult to criticise models of this sort. To argue that it is not realistic, would be besides the point. It does not attempt to explain an empirical phenomenon, so it cannot fail in this respect. Of course, one might criticise it for making unrealistic assumption (for instance CRS - Constant Returns to Scale), but this is a relatively standard assumption. One might argue that Sen's way of modelling prefernces is a bit curious; Why not include other people's welfare directly in your utility function if you really care about other people (and not through the extended preference function as Sen has done)? However, doing so would not change the conclusion (Sen says), so it is not a serious objection here. One might also criticise the model for leaving out some variables. For instance, the payment method does not only determine the size of the current cake, but also size of the future cake (rate of growth, innovation). This (may) give greater force to the "pay according to effort" argument, but it is a question of degrees.

I guess the point of the model is really to show something that we previously had not given close thought. When faced with an incentive system that does not pay according to effort, most people (including me) immediately responds that it must be more efficient to change it so effort is given a greater reward. Sen's model shows that this need not be true, and he shows the variables that determine the relationship. In this sense the model is valuable; it produces a rigorous, policy relevant and surprising result.

Conclusion
This review is supposed to form the starting point for a larger reflection on the use of models and formal reasoning in economics. The point of this review was simply to present a model since I believe a methodological discussion on the use of models should be based on concrete examples. the next essay will also present a model (a somewhat easier and shorter model), while the last essay will be a more verbal discussion of some of the arguments (including those presented by Paul Krugman in the essay "Two cheers for formalism" and his book about economic theory, development economics and economic geography.

Reference
Sen, A. (1966), Labour allocation in a cooperative enterprise, Review of Economic Studies, vol. 33, no. 96, pp. 363-371
Moene, K.O., Lecturenotes



[Note for bibliographic reference: Melberg, Hans O. (1998), Pay according to need or effort? A starting point for thinking about the value of models in economics , www.oocities.org/hmelberg/papers/980303.htm]