Personal Website of R.Kannan
Students Corner - Project on Monetary Policy
Assessment of Key Issues

Home Table of Contents Feedback



Visit Title Page
Students Corner



Back to First Page of Module: 5 to view
index of articles

Project on Assessment of Key Issues Related to Monetary Policy
[Source: RBI Report on Currency & Finance 2003-04]

Module: 5 Bank Credit

Bank Credit to Government

The banking system is a source for funds for not only the private sector but also for the government sector. In India, with progressive widening of fiscal deficits from 1960s onwards, the burden of financing has been borne by the Reserve Bank and the banking system. As the Reserve Bank financing beyond a limit is inflationary, the increase in the Reserve Bank support to the Central Government was accompanied by an increase in cash reserve requirements (CRR). As regards the support of the banking system to the Government's borrowing programme, it took the form of a progressive increase in the SLR. Although interest rates on Government securities - initially kept artificially low to contain the interest cost of public debt - were steadily raised to enhance their attractiveness to the market, it got increasingly difficult to get voluntary subscriptions even at higher rates of return. The SLR, therefore, was raised to 38.5 per cent by the early 1990s and coupled with the increase in the CRR, statutory pre-emptions exceeded 60 per cent of total resources. This curtailed banks' lendable resources significantly and, as noted above, credit to the commercial sector (as a proportion to GDP) showed a near stagnation during the 1980s and 1990s. As a proportion to their deposits, bank credit to the commercial sector exhibited a sharp decline during the 1970s. The declining trend continued during the 1980s, albeit at a moderate pace (Chart VI.4). Non-food credit by scheduled commercial banks was as high as 76 per cent of their deposits in March 1971; the ratio fell to 60 per cent by March 1990.

As a part of the reform process, the statutory pre-emptions were cut and, at present, these are just half of their early 1990s level. The SLR, in particular, was reduced from 38.5 per cent to 25 per cent by 1997. This reduction in SLR was expected to reduce banks' holdings of the Government paper and correspondingly lead to a higher flow of credit to the private sector. Notwithstanding the flexibility provided by the new regime, the holdings of the banks in the Government securities remain significantly higher than the requirements and, in fact, tended to increase over time. By early October 2004, scheduled commercial banks' holdings of SLR securities amounted to around 40 per cent of their net demand and time liabilities (NDTL) as compared with the required 25 per cent.

A cross-country analysis shows that lending by banks in India to the Government (as per cent to GDP) is comparable to many developing economies but higher than some of the East Asian economies (Table 6.10). Illustratively, during 2001-03, bank credit to Government in India was almost 27 per cent of GDP, significantly higher than that of two per cent in Korea. This is in sharp contrast to the earlier noted trend in regard to credit extended to the private sector where the ratios for these economies vastly exceed that of India.

A number of factors explain the banks' preference for holding excess Government securities. First, demand for private credit moderated following the slowdown of the Indian economy from 1997-98 onwards. Available empirical evidence suggests that there is a co-movement between output and credit demand. Downward rigidity in the lending rates of the banks could also have reduced demand for bank credit. Econometric analysis suggests that real non-food credit is positively related to output and negatively related to interest rates. Estimated elasticity of real non-food credit of 1.6 suggests that demand for real non-food credit increases more than the increase in output (Box VI.4).

Second, capital flows from abroad have been quite strong since 1993-94 (see Chapter IV). This increased the availability of funds with the banks and, in view of weak credit demand, banks preferred to invest these surplus funds in Government securities. Third, a key factor appears to be the fiscal deficit of the Government which has continued to remain high. Market borrowing requirements of the Government sector have, therefore, been increasing. Weak credit demand coupled with increased funds due to capital inflows enabled banks to invest in the Government paper. Otherwise, the pressure to finance the fisc could have rever ted to the Reser ve Bank or alternatively, it could have led to pressures on interest rates.

Fourth, the preference of the banks for investment in Government securities was also influenced by the phased tightening of prudential norms on capital adequacy, asset classification and income recognition to international standards. These prudential guidelines could have increased risk aversion on the part of the banks to private sector lending, since the credit risk-free Government paper requires zero provisioning. Thus, capital adequacy requirements of banks increases substantially while extending credit to the private sector but no such addition is required while investing in Government paper. Fifth, in an environment of softening interest rates, which prevailed for an extended period of time - from around 1998 onwards till early-2004 -investment in Government securities also turned out to be relatively attractive. In fact, the treasury operations of banks have been a significant source of their profitability in the past few years. These profits strengthened banks' balance sheets and enabled them to provide resources for NPA provisioning. Finally, another reason of risk aversion to lending to the private sector could be that the loan officers worry about the possibility of being falsely accused of corruption. Banerjee, Cole and Dufflo (2003) find some empirical support in favour of this proposition.

The banks' preference for gilts had a few benefits. First, as noted above, in the past couple of years, it boosted banks' profitability and balance sheets. Second, excessive lending in times of poor growth could have generated problems of adverse selection. At the same time, large investments in gilts raise a number of concerns. First, it reflects dissipation of banking knowledge capital with regard to credit appraisals and runs a danger of the link between liquidity, credit, money and economic activity being severed in the long-run. Second, in view of the excess investments, the burden of funding the borrowings could revert to the Reserve Bank which makes monetary management difficult. Finally, investment in Government securities are subject to market risks arising from fluctuations in market rates of interest. With the upturn of the interest rate cycle, there could be an adverse impact on banks' profitability. In this context, it is relevant to observe that the Reserve Bank had advised banks to build-up Investment Fluctuation Reserves (IFR) to meet such eventualities.


Box VI.4
Determinants of Bank Credit

Bank credit is an important source of working capital for corporates and timely availability of credit contributes to economic activity. Supply of bank credit depends, inter alia, upon availability of funds with the banks, the rate at which they lend and returns on alternative instruments of investment (such as Government securities, commercial paper and equity markets). Although supply of credit is important, actual utilisation of credit would depend upon its demand. With growing financial liberalisation, the available pool of resources has expanded to include not only bank credit but also external resources such as external commercial borrowings, foreign currency convertible bonds and equity funds through depository receipts. Thus, due to a variety of reasons there can be a switch from a regime of credit rationing to a situation of demand constraint in the loan market .

For India, evidence suggests that there exists a bi-directional causality between output and credit, i.e., changes in credit lead to changes in output and vice versa (RBI, 2003). In contrast to these aggregate data, Misra (2003) undertook a state-wise analysis of relationship between credit and output. For most of the states, he found evidence in favour of a unidirectional causation from output to credit. His results suggest that credit flow to various states is guided by the absorptive capacity of the states. Lack of credit off-take, in this view, should not be seen as a problem in itself but should be seen in conjunction with growth prospects of the concerned states. According to estimates contained in RBI (2003), demand for credit is positively influenced by lagged as well as contemporaneous output while interest rates depress credit demand. Supply of credit was found to have a positive relationship with lending rates, banks' free reserves and equity prices. Rath and Bose (2004) estimate demand and supply for credit in a vector error correction framework and find that output is a key determinant of credit demand while availability of funds with banks determines the supply of loans by banks. Industry-wise estimates of credit elasticities show that these vary across industries. Credit elasticity is relatively low for industries such as food products and cotton textiles and high for industries like engineering (RBI, 2002). With the changing composition of industrial output over time, overall credit demand elasticity may undergo change.

This Box attempts to re-examine the behaviour of credit and its determinants in India. First, hypothesis of a bi-directional causality between output and credit cannot be rejected1 . Second, in order to understand the determinants of demand for credit, the relationship between credit, output and interest rates is examined in an autoregressive distributed lag (ARDL) model of order (1,0,0). Results indicate that credit demand increases by 1.6 per cent for every one per cent increase in real GDP. Third, the negative influence of lending rates on credit demand is statistically significant, although the effect is small. Estimates suggest that a reduction of 10 percentage points in the lending rate would increase credit demand by around one per cent.

Although long-run relationship between these three variables is confirmed, it is also interesting to examine the short-run dynamics as there have been periods such as 1997-98 when credit continued to expand even as activity was sluggish. This could occur if, in the face of weak demand conditions, inventory builds-up and this increases firms demand for short-term credit. As firms adjust over time to reduced demand, they curtail production and run down the inventories and, in turn, this will reduce credit demand. The dynamics of this adjustment process can be examined through estimation of an error correction model. The results show that the error correction term is statistically significant. The coefficient estimate of 0.21 of the error correction term indicates that the adjustment process is relatively fast and one-fifth of the deviation from the equilibrium is corrected every year. Thus, periods when credit and output do not show a co-movement are short-lived and, over time, the positive co-movement is restored. Estimates of credit elasticities attempted here have covered the period 1975-2003 - a period involving a regime shift from a credit-regulated economy where interest rates did not play an equilibrating role between demand and supply to a regime where credit supply and demand both depend upon market forces. Against this backdrop, the empirical evidence and the estimated elasticities should be treated as indicative.


On the positive side, the pick-up in investment activity in the economy from the second half of 2003 onwards has led to a strong credit demand from the private sector. Correspondingly, investments of the banking system in Government securities have recorded a significant deceleration. The enactment of the Fiscal Responsibility and Budget Management Act, 2003 with its envisaged reduction in fiscal deficits will help to reduce banks' investment in gilts and, correspondingly, this is expected to enhance the credit flow to the private sector.


- - - : ( End of Module: 5 ) : - - -

Previous                  Top

[..Page Last Updated on 15.02.2005..]<>[Chkd-Apvd]