Reforming
the EU before enlargement - the need for a "European Social
Model"
- (NIC)
On the 12th
of December in Copenhagen begins a summit where the EU is expected
to confirm the accession of ten candidate states in 2004. On the
19th of October, the Irish voted "yes" to the Nice treaty,
paving the way for the planned enlargement in 2004. But what kind
of Europe are the candidate countries about to join? Europe has
evolved significantly since the days of Jean Monnet(1)
and Robert Schuman(2) . These statesmen envisaged
creating peace on the continent by integrating the economies of
potential rivals to such an extent that another war would be financially
impossible. In the words of the Schuman declaration(3)
(Schuman, 1950), "The solidarity in production thus established
will make it plain than any way between France and Germany becomes
not merely unthinkable, but materially impossible". Beyond
this, Schumann envisaged that "This production will be offered
to the world as a whole without distinction or exception, with
the aim of contributing to raising living standards and to promoting
peaceful achievements." Unification was therefore conceived
as a force for peace and stability in a continent ravaged by wars
and genocide. The single market was merely to be a means to this
end. The problem is that early on, the single market, or rather
the free market, became an end in itself(4) .
The distinction
between the single market and the free market is an important
one. For example, the Soviet Union was a vast single market, but
most definitely not a free market. The single market is not inherently
flawed, as long as the rules are enforced. A single market in
the absence of enforceable rules leads to inequalities between
member states. For example, France and Germany recently angered
their smaller partners in the single-currency zone by threatening
to breach the rules of the "stability pact", whereby
national budget deficits should not exceed 3%. This is the very
same stability pact, which had been insisted upon by the German
central bank in order to keep the "less disciplined"
economies in line (Black, 2002b)! These problems illustrate the
dangers of a single market in the absence of a powerful federal
government. But in many ways, the free-market is far more problematic.
As shown on the other side of the Atlantic, self-regulation of
markets leads to corruption and abuse. This is best illustrated
by the downfall of Enron, WorldCom, Arthur Anderson etc. and the
consequent loss of jobs, pensions and revenue for the ordinary
citizens, employees and shareholders. Another suicidal trend is
the privatisation of services, despite disasters such as the collapse
of Railtrack, the privatised British rail operator. Similarly,
the privatised British National Air Traffic Services are causing
the worse flight delays in Europe (Moss, 2002). Other examples
include the privatisation of the power-generating industry in
Britain and Sweden, which led to a rise in the price of electricity
for consumers!
Proponents
of market self-regulation are contradicted not only by the facts,
but also by such prominent analysts as Joseph Stiglitz, Nobel
Prize-winner in Economy and former director of the World Bank
(Stiglitz, 2002). In his latest book, Stiglitz warns of the dangers
of excessive liberalisation, whose proponents are more often influenced
by ideology than proven success. Even the international financier
George Soros(5) admits that not only are
the markets incapable of self-regulation, but they are also "amoral".
By "amoral", he means that the markets are incapable
of providing the basic needs of mankind, such as health, culture,
education, social services, policing etc. (Nora, 2002). The UN
Human Development Index adds weight to this argument, showing
that the top 10% earners in the USA grab 30% of total national
income, a figure comparable to Turkey. Yet even the United States
is not a true free market, as illustrated by recent plans to increase
state subsidies to agriculture by 70% (Jarreau, 2002), state intervention
to save floundering airlines, and illegal plans (under WTO legislation)
to subsidise an ailing steel industry (Anonymous, 2002a). Unfortunately,
the EU seems to be suffering from the delusion that the success
of the American economy lies in unbridled capitalism, whereas
in reality it relies on a great deal of protectionism.
The EU planners
tend to dismiss all the evidence and pursue the holy grail of
deregulation, at the expense of democratic governance. For example,
the fifteen member states agreed recently to a total liberalisation
of the power industry. In doing so, they threaten what is left
of the "European Social Model". True, the EU "Social
Model" can boast achievements as the Europe-wide minimum
wage, the protection of cultural minorities, and the redistribution
of wealth to the poorer regions. But it is generally an illusion,
because it is constantly overruled by the requirements of the
single market(6) . For example, the Barcelona Convention, which
contained agreements for basic services to be taken out of the
people's hands, paved the way for privatisation of transport and
communications (Cassen, 2002). Thus, the European Social Model
needs to be resurrected rather than preserved.
In reality,
the "democratic deficit" extends well beyond the financial
arena. For example, the unelected Commission still has disproportionate
powers compared to the more accountable European Parliament. Secondly,
there is no framework for submitting major changes to the national
electorates. One laudable exception is Ireland, which organised
a referendum on the Nice Treaty, a pathetic compromise attempt
at reform that contained few democratic improvements on the existing
model. The people used this rare opportunity to reject it. No
matter, it was re-submitted to them in the same format, and they
were asked to vote again, and would have been asked to do so repeatedly
until they answered "yes". Now that they have chosen
the "correct" answer, their decision is irreversible.
The Nice Treaty contains no major improvements to address the
democratic deficit. Most of the amendments presented in the treaty
preserve the merely consultative role of the Parliament. The only
major power of the Parliament is the ability to force a group
resignation of the Commission, which led to the downfall of Jacques
Santer's Commission. In important matters such as foreign, economic
and security policy, the Parliament is merely informed or consulted.
This does not leave much flexibility for the Parliament to be
involved in the daily running of European affairs. The democratic
deficit also extends to Eastern Europe, where none of the applicant
countries have organised referenda on joining the EU.
Beyond the
democratic deficit, Europe also suffers from its lack of political
strength in the world. Enlargement, far from consolidating what
little influence the EU has in the world, risks diluting it further.
One reason is the announced NATO membership of the new applicant
countries, which will ensure that EU will find it difficult to
develop an independent defence policy, and that its forces will
be "subordinate to American whim" (Kilfoyle, 2002).
For the same reason, the Bush administration is putting a lot
of pressure on the EU to begin accession talks with Turkey, another
NATO member, and staunch ally of the United States. In a similar
vein, the European Rapid Reaction force was doomed from the start
by agreements that Turkey should be involved, and that NATO should
have a veto over its use of military equipment. Meanwhile, the
UK's alignment with US foreign policy is almost total, and often
puts Britain at odds with its European partners. Maybe it is time
for Britain to realise that the "special relationship"
with the USA is a one-sided affair. Without more commitment on
Britain's part, the EU cannot have a coherent stance in World
affairs, without the EU to defend the principles of international
justice in the face of Bush's unilateralism, the United Nations
will lose all credibility.
EU foreign
policy is no more independent than its defence. The International
Criminal Court is a good example. The EU pushed very hard for
the creation of this body, which is an essential component of
international justice. Then, it betrayed its own stated ideals
and caved in to American demands. Hence, in early October, the
EU agreed to allow member states to make deals exempting US citizens
from being tried at the ICC for war crimes (Black, 2002). International
justice was the first victim, considering that a meeting of EU
legal experts in September had concluded that the US demands for
bilateral agreements were illegal (Zecchini, 2002). The deal also
destroyed any hope of a common judicial policy for the EU: how
can one have an integrated management of crime when some states
will fail to submit war criminals to international justice?
EU foreign
policy weaknesses are also deleterious to the rest of the world,
because they contribute to its unipolarity. As described by Peter
Kilfoyle a British labour MP, "a unipolar World is a dangerous
place. It is like standing on one leg - one is far more liable
to lose balance than when one is standing on two, or even four
legs. Increasingly, it is clear that there needs to be an effective
counterbalance to this over-powering US hegemony."(Kilfoyle,
2002). The EU financed many reconstruction projects in Palestine
(Kilfoyle, 2002), only to see them destroyed by Israeli incursions.
The EU is unable to prevent such scandals because it has no effective
foreign policy instruments, and essentially no more than a glorified
satellite state of its more powerful ally. The war against Iraq
is another example of the USA trying to drag European countries
into wars their people do not wish. Governments like Tony Blair's
have long since ceased to question American motives, and other
European countries will follow suit if a coherent and independent
Federation does not emerge in the old continent. In the case of
Iraq, Europe could say "no", merely by exercising its
vetoes at the Security Council and NATO. A strong EU could at
least moderate the excesses of its American friend.
In light of
these shortcomings, the EU needs more than reform, it needs a
structural revolution. The first step in this revolution is the
drafting of a proper Constitution. According to the political
analyst Dominique Rousseau (7), a Constitution is a radical change
because of its implications; the difference between a Constitution
and a Treaty is that a treaty is agreed upon by sovereign states,
whereas a Constitution would represent the peoples of Europe.
Thus, the Constitution implies a federal Europe, where politics
are no longer a tool for furthering national interests, but a
means of representing the collective will of the citizens of Europe.
In Rousseau's view, the Constitution would finally turn Europe
into a representative democracy, accountable to its citizens.
For this to happen, the Constitution must be submitted to the
collective approval of the citizens of Europe by a collective
vote (Rousseau, 2002). Thus, a Constitution involves far more
than cosmetic changes to the existing treaties, it involves a
total rethink of the inner workings of the EU. However, this idea
is already threatened by the Convention on the Future of Europe,
which is suggesting the far less ambitious and judicially contradictory
(Rousseau, 2002) term of "Constitutional Treaty".
Regardless,
many have already proposed their own version of what a Constitution
should contain. Some, like Robert Badinter (8) (2002), French
Socialist Senator, are true to the Constitutionalist spirit and
propose a reinforcement of the European Parliament, which is divided
along political rather than national lines. Others, such as Jack
Straw (9) (2002) and The Economist, wish to use the future document
to sabotage any further social developments, preserving Europe
as merely a large free-trade area, and reinforcing the power of
national parliaments. At first, this may seem a democratic move,
but under close scrutiny, it is a move to weaken the EU as a political
entity. Devolution and the principle of subsidiarity are important
in order to preserve cultural diversity and to cater for regional
needs. However, there is no reason why this devolution should
benefit national parliaments rather than the regions. Moreover,
on key issues of foreign policy, Straw's proposals would paralyse
the EU. Indeed, a vote in the European Parliament will be swift
and decisive, whereas waiting for 25 or more Parliaments to respond
rapidly and to come to a consensus is unrealistic. A paralysed
political system will leave the market forces unchallenged. Moreover,
granting more powers to national parliaments only encourages EU
citizens to think along nationalistic or even xenophobic lines.
The nation states of Europe are an artificial construct of the
19th century, and have been the cause of several crippling wars.
The entire founding principle of the European Coal and Steel Community
was to encourage the peoples of Europe to come together as one,
and to put an end to nationalism and war. Granting more powers
to the European Parliament will encourage people to think beyond
their narrowly defined boundaries, and to realise that they share
ideas with people all over the continent. The Schengen area, which
allows freedom of movement from state to state, was a start, a
common government is the next logical step.
The 105 member
Convention includes representatives of national governments and
parliaments, the European Parliament and Commission, and is engaged
in consulting the public and civil society, through various means,
which include the online posting of suggestions. However, there
is no obligation on the part of Giscard's team to take the suggestions
into account, and there are no plans to submit the final draft
to a Europe-wide referendum. The Nice treaty mentions civil society
essentially as being allowed to participate in bodies such as
the Economic and Social Committee, which is purely advisory. The
citizens of Europe must be more actively involved in designing
the future of our continent. In this context, Europe-wide referenda
should be organised concerning any major new treaties. But the
occasional "yes" or "no" referendum is far
from enough. Regional democracy, based on the Danish model of
"consensus conferences", or on the Swiss model of "citizen's
petitions", is essential. At the federal level, democracy
can be enhanced only by reinforcing the role of Parliament, at
the expense of the Commission and Council of Ministers. If there
is to be a European head of State, then she or he would be more
democratically credible if chosen by the Parliament (Badinter,
2002), or even directly by the people of Europe.
Whatever it
contains, the Constitution should be written in simple terms,
free of the usual jargon, and understandable by the majority of
the population. It should clearly state the boundaries of supranational
and national authorities, as well as allowing for the secession
of member states, which are entirely dissatisfied with the Union
(this idea has already been mentioned as a possibility by the
Convention). Conversely, the Constitution should allow for certain
member states to go ahead with reinforced cooperation and integration,
even if others do not wish to be involved. There must also be
a clear hierarchy in the implementation of different clauses,
with a priority on social and environmental aspects. The social
aspects can be integrated in the constitution as part of a "social
contract" as suggested by Elisabeth Guigou (10) (2002). This
would grant protection to public services, the alignment of social
norms to the highest common denominator, and the guarantee of
a minimum wage based on the wealth of each member state. Finally,
the Constitution must imperatively incorporate the European Charter
of Fundamental (Human) Rights, which was signed in Nice in 2000.
With their integration into the Constitution, "…the rights
enshrined in the Charter, beyond their moral value, will have
legal power" (Badinter, 2002).
Reform must
also lead to a better world outside our borders, not only because
this is morally desirable, but also because it will help Europe
avoid the blowback that the USA is currently experiencing for
decades of misguided foreign entanglements. Europe must have a
solid commitment to international law (e.g. no deals that could
undermine the ICC), and a renouncement to the dangerous concept
of "preventative warfare". A large entity such as the
EU, if it were committed to the principles of the United Nations,
could save the latter from becoming irrelevant in the face of
recent challenges by the Bush administration. In the same way
that European determination saved the Kyoto Environmental Protocol
after the American pullout, the collective allegiance of 25 European
nations can help consolidate the United Nations.
Beyond international
legislation, the EU commitment should be to fair trade rather
than free trade. We could start by reducing weapons sales to developing
countries. Britain recently tried to sell a £28 million
military air traffic control system to Tanzania, a country ravaged
by AIDS and malnutrition. Worse, the World Bank recently published
a report saying the system should have cost one ninth of that
price (Hencke, 2002). The reformed EU must be able to block such
deals. If allowed to trade fairly, many developing nations would
not require so much foreign aid. In the words of a recent Guardian
editorial: "What stinks is that the west has been peddling
free trade as a route out of poverty while protecting the sort
of industries that should be open to competition from developing
countries" (Anonymous, 2002a). In fact, the Third World needs
to be allowed a certain amount of protectionism before its industry
can reach a level where it can compete on more equal terms with
our own. The much-derided Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) is
in severe need of alteration. The CAP subsidies result in a gargantuan
overproduction, which then drives down world food prices to a
level where third world farmers earn almost nothing for their
exports (Anonymous, 2002c). It is not surprising that as a result,
many farmers turn to the production of poppies to ensure their
survival. The 40 billion a year of subsidies should be reserved
to save the farmers of applicant countries from economic ruin
when they join the EU, not "…to pay for producing food nobody
wants, keeping third-world farmers poor and wrecking Europe's
rural environment…" (Anonymous, 2002c).
Blair, Aznar
and Berlusconi's abominable proposals for a "Fortress Europe"
strategy towards immigration must also be resisted. Jack Straw
(2002) proposes a common European asylum policy, in order "…to
deal with illegal immigration and the criminality which underlies
it". The criminals who are paid enormous sums and treat their
desperate human cargo like cattle should of course be prosecuted.
However, the notion "illegal immigrant" criminalizes
the victims of this human trade, which is repugnant. In any case,
how can a person be "illegal"? We criminalize these
people by making the rules for immigration unbelievably severe.
The fascist-leaning trend to try and distinguish between "those
genuinely fleeing tyranny and oppression" (Straw, 2002) and
the "economic" (i.e. illegal) migrants is based on false
logic. Should it make a difference if your family is dying of
malnutrition or of "tyranny and oppression"? Isn't the
economic imperialism of the west a form of oppression? Is it unreasonable
for people to leave a country where they cannot offer a future
to their children, a country where their life expectancy is reduced
to below 50 years by economic meltdown? Even if we are morally
insensitive enough to ignore these issues, the ageing population
of Europe is in severe need of new blood, and therefore of immigration.
Thus, the new Europe should forsake its phobia of "illegal
immigration" and deal instead with the reasons why people
emigrate in the first place, as well as guaranteeing the basic
human rights of those who end up on our shores. Aznar would do
well to remember that just 20 years ago, his country's economy
was sorely dependent on income from Spanish emigrants working
in the richer parts of Europe. What would have become of Spain
if it had been locked out of "Fortress Europe"?
The European
Union has clearly moved on from Schumann's Coal and Steel Community.
The Cold war is over, and the single market has essentially been
achieved. European unification has successfully averted the risk
of further wars in Western Europe, and has significantly reduced
the poverty of countries such as Greece, Ireland, Spain and Portugal.
But these achievements are meaningless if our enrichment is at
the expense of the third-world, if it contributes to greater inequality,
or of we are unable to stop United Nations from suffering the
same fate as pre-war League of Nations. We must move away from
a Europe where politics have been dethroned by the rules of free
market and competition, stripping the most vulnerable of vital
social protection. Despite all its shortcomings, the EU is essential
not only as a shield against the worst aspects of globalisation,
but also as an economic safety net for Eastern Europe(11)
. However, only radical social reforms can consolidate these achievements
and ensure that its citizens, and international law, are not left
behind.
Notes
1- 1883-1979. France's Planning Commissionner in 1950. Often seen, along with Schuman, as the founding father of the European Community.
2- 1886-1963. Schuman was the French foreign minister in the 1950s.
3- Of 9th May 1950, establishing the European Coal and Steel Community.
4- Or maybe the EU never was designed with social justice in mind.
5- International speculator, most famous for bringing the British Pound crashing out of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism
5- See the essay "A European Court for the Environment" ,on this site, for a similar conflict between single-market imperatives and environmental legislation.
6- Professor of Constitutional Law at the Montpellier University, France 7- French Socialist Senator 8- British Foreign Minister
9- Former Socialist minister in France. Currently MP for Seine-St-Denis
10- The people of Cyprus are particularly keen to join, since Europe will offer them, at least theoretically, some amount of protection from Turkey
References
Anonymous.
2002a. An unequal world. The Guardian, 13/04/02
Anonymous. 2002b. Ever droopier union. The Economist, 365(8294):
41-42
Anonymous. 2002c. Scandalous. The Economist, 365(8292): 13
Badinter, R. 2002. Les deux souverainetés. Le Nouvel Observateur.1979:
41
Black, I. 2002. UK accused of sacrificing new criminal court.
The Guardian Weekly. 03/10/02
Black, I. 2002b. EU's big boys override rulebook on budgetary
limits. The Guardian Weekly, 03/10/02.
Cassen, B. 2002. Est-il encore utile de voter après le
sommet de Barcelone? Le Monde Diplomatique, April 2002
Guigou, E. 2002. Europe: réussir l'élargissement.
Le Monde, 25/10/02.
Hencke, D. 2002. Tanzania aviation deal a "waste of money".
The Guardian Weekly, 20/06/02
Kilfoyle, P. 2002. In defence of Europe. The Guardian Weekly,
03/10/02
Leclère, M.F. 2002. Réussir sa vie. Le Point, 1569:
28-42
Leparmentier, A. 2002. Paris refuse de s'engager sur la reduction
de son deficit budgétaire. Le Monde, 09/10/02
Moss, L. 2002. UK has worst flight delays in Europe. Cyprus Mail,
27/08/02
Nora, D. 2002. Docteur George & Mister Soros. Le Nouvel Observateur,
03/10/02
Rousseau, D. 2002. "Traité constitutionnel",
un monster juridique. Le Monde, 22/10/02
Schumann, R. 1950. Declaration of 9 May 1950. Europa. http://europa.eu.int/abc/symbols/9-may/decl_en.html.
18/10/02
Stiglitz, J. 2002. Globalization and its discontents. Penguin
Press, UK
Straw, J. 2002. A Constitution for Europe. The Economist, 365(8294):
41-42
Zecchini, L. 2002. Le compromis ambigu des Quinze sur la CPI.
Le Monde, 02/10/02
|