EUROPEAN INTEGRATION Common Agricultural Policy of the European Union By MARAL
EROL INTRODUCTION: Common Agricultural
Policy of the European Union, which is going to be called shortly as CAP throughout this
paper, has an interesting story of how a policy started with good intentions turn to a
giant monster eating more than half of the Community budget. A considerable part of that
story constitutes of the efforts to stop that monster. Today, CAP is one of the most
important, most problematic and most developed areas of the Community policy. It is
certainly the most expensive policy, with a cost of about
two thirds of the budget in the 1970's and still half of it; while it contributes only
around 2,5 % to the total GDP and employs less than 7 % of the workforce in the 1990's. [1] It is also a widely criticized policy
by the third countries, for it prevents the international free trade by protectionist
measures. CAP started
as an effort to harmonize the agricultural policies of the member states and to give them
a new direction through a more productive agricultural sector. This aim was over
successfully reached and this time a problem of overproduction occurred, which brings a
heavy burden on the EU budget because of the highly protective nature of the CAP. As a
result, efforts to reform CAP has been made, since the 1980's. In the first part of
this paper, I will try to elaborate on the importance, history and future of CAP. The
second part of this paper deals with the Turkish aspect of the question; with references
to the main agreements concerning the subject, comparisons of Turkish agriculture and that
of the EU, a brief sectoral analysis of the agricultural products in terms of their
competency in the EU markets and lastly an examination of the effects of Turkey's
membership on the EU and on Turkey itself. PART 1 I. IMPORTANCE OF CAP: The importance of CAP
(and also the nature of its formation) is
related to the importance of agriculture as a whole and the importance of having an
agricultural policy in general. The first reason of
why agriculture is so special is the nature of its products. Most of the agricultural
products are vital necessities, and that forces the governments to follow a protectionist
path in dealing with the agriculture. Second problem is the
production process: Usually, technically most efficient way of production harms the
society, (e.g. Small farmers cannot compete with big and highly efficient "agro
business" companies.) and also the environment. So, governments and other decision making institutions have to find a
balance between efficiency and its costs in
determining an agricultural policy. The third problem is
the degree of uncertainty involved in the agricultural production. Weather conditions play
an important role in the volume and quality of the product, and sometimes an unpredicted
factor, such as animal disease can cause big fluctuations in the production and
consumption patterns. All these characteristics make agriculture a very volatile area of
policymaking, and these are reflected in the CAP. Agriculture was a
matter of concern for the Community, especially in the foundation process. There were
several motives for this concern: 1) The European
countries came out of the 2nd World War, and the memories of that major war was crucial in
forming their policies afterwards. Most of them were nearly starving, for agricultural
surpluses went low, so this made them take every possible measure to guarantee an
agricultural surplus in case of an emergency in the 1950's. 2) Agriculture was not
a very efficient sector in the 1950’s, it needed protection for further growth. The
farmers usually had a lower standard of living than the rest of the population. 3) France, which is an
important political actor in the process of creating a common Europe, had a relatively
large agricultural sector, and it wanted to protect this sector against the industrially
developed economy of Germany. 4) Agricultural vote
was (and still is) very important in most of the European countries, especially in France.
There is a problem of overrepresentation of farmers living in the sparsely populated
agricultural areas as opposed to crowded cities, because of the nature of the
representation system. As a result of al
these conditions, CAP came out to be highly protective policy, strongly favoring the
farming sector. II. HISTORY OF THE CAP: A. 1950's and 1960's: The first document on
agricultural policy was the Spaak Report, prepared in 1956. Its
importance comes from the fact that it set the scene for introduction of agriculture into
the Treaty of Rome. Wider objective of the report was "creation of the common market,
within which agriculture was but one sector. "[2] So, in the beginning, the aim was a
limited protectionism, not isolated from the rest of the world. However, creating a common
market for agriculture was a more complex task than creating one in other sectors, mostly because of national regulations and
concerns. Treaty of Rome stated
that a common agricultural policy should be pursued (article 3), and it set a transition
period extending from 1958 to 1970 (article 40). The objectives and principles were stated
in the articles 38 to 47 of the treaty. According to these the original objectives, as stated in article 39 of the treaty were: 1. To increase
agricultural productivity by promoting technical progress and the optimum use of
production factors, 2. To ensure a fair
standard of living to the agricultural community by increasing their per capita income. 3. To stabilize
markets. 4. To assure
availability of supplies. 5. To ensure
reasonable consumer prices. Since the second and
the fifth points are in conflict the editors tried to indicate some priority by the order
of the points.[3] In article 43 of the
treaty it is stated that a conference on a common agricultural policy should be convened
to elaborate on the main lines of that policy. That conference was held in Stresa, in
1958. This was the conference that the CAP was founded formally, with two kinds of
necessary policies: " I) a policy of
market control (including the following three elements of the treaty) ;
-
a market regulation, comprising an intervening body, competition rules and rules for
foreign trade;
-
a price policy, consisting in the setting of minimum prices by criteria as objective as
possible;
-
a fund to pay guaranteed prices (guarantee); II) a structural
policy ;
-
production factors;
-
production conditions;
-
involving a fund for financing this policy at the EC level."[4] All implementations of
the common policy of market control are based on three principles: 1. Unity of the
European market: Completely free
traffic of agricultural products and a common organization to set one price for the whole
market and to used the same intervention instruments in all member states. Besides, mutual
adjustments on health, quality measures, etc. were thought of. 2. Priority for
EC's own products: Imports will be
resorted to only if the European production is insufficient. 3. Financial
solidarity: That found expression
in the European Agricultural Fund's Guarantee Division. All levies were to be paid in to
the EAGGF, regardless of who collects them and all costs were to be paid from it no matter
which state they are paid to. Usually, income of that fund, i.e. import levies from
agricultural goods, was not sufficient to meet the expenses, and other financial means of
the Community were used to compensate that difference. Guarantee Division is the more
expensive part of EAGGF, for it is the part responsible for storage costs and subsidies,
which make a large amount of EAGGF budget. The systems of market
control and regulation are not the same for all agricultural products. Roughly, there are
three systems: The first system (or
scheme) applies to about 70 % of the production, namely cereals, sugar, beef and dairy
products. These are the "classical" products among 22 product groups. There is minimum guaranteed
wholesale price, below which the intervention boards buy up the surplus. Similar market
schemes also apply to pork, fruit and vegetables and table wine, with more emphasis on
storage and processing support rather than automatic sales guarantee at a fixed price. The second system can
be called as "limited free price formation". Where there are variable levies on
the imports from third countries to constrain their consumption, thus to create a more
favorable environment for the Community products. This scheme consists of certain fruits
and vegetables, flowers, eggs and fattened poultry, which are products with a short
production cycle and which are not among the basic needs. Together, they make up about 25
% of the agricultural production. The third scheme is a system of bonuses based on the
quantity produced. It constitutes less than 5 % of the production, and is applied for
products such as oilseeds and olive oil; to allow domestic production to be maintained at
high producer costs, yet with consumer prices kept low. Besides that
three-legged system, there is an export refund, paid to Community exporters, who export
agricultural surpluses to third countries. In the financial side of that system, one fixed
price should prevail throughout the market for the whole Community. However, the Community
did not have a currency of its own, so the price was first expressed in ECU, and then
recalculated in the national currencies. This meant that the changes in the exchange rate
may cause price differences. To balance this, a system of levies and restitutions in the
interior frontiers were introduced. This system was called MCA: Monetary Compensatory
Amounts. However, that was breaking the unity and was later given up. On the structural part
of agricultural policy, things developed slower than the market regulation part. A serious
effort of coordination was needed before creating a common structural policy for
agriculture. This was achieved by the Mansholt Plan, in 1968, and elaborated on
through the 1970's. In its present form, it has three main elements, and the costs of it
are met by the EAGGF, Guidance Division. The parts of the structural policy are: 1. Support to
management: It means support to
investments aimed at technical progress, interest and investment subsidies. Another forms
of support is improving educational and training possibilities for the farmers. For this
aim, a network of consulting agencies is built up. 2. Improvement of
the trade channels for agricultural produce: Subsidies are also
given to trade channels such as packing establishments, cold storage warehouses, dairy
factories, slaughter houses, etc. There are also funds for producers to found
cooperatives. 3. Reduction of
regional differences: Theses are supporting
measures in the framework of an integrated development program. Agriculture has not
figured as a subject in the later amendments, SEA and Maastricht, but continuous reform
programs were adopted, because of the problems caused by the initial agricultural policy. B. Problems of the Initial System: The initial CAP, as
stated in the Treaty of Rome and the Stresa Conference and elaborated by the reforms of
1960's, turned into a rather problematic system in the 1970's. Primary reasons for that
are as follows: a) Objectives of
aiming at both producer and consumer satisfaction were in conflict, and in time it became
clear that the system strongly favors the farmers, not the consumers. b) Open ended nature
of the support mechanism led to overproduction. Effective internal EC price was very high,
because the standard measure of that price was decided as the highest price among all
member states. Farmers were also protected
from outside effects by import restrictions. Moreover, they did not have a problem of
finding a market, because of guarantee buyings. As a result, the more they produced, the
more they gained, and there was no limit for that guarantee. In a sense, that can
be seen as a success, for one of the original objectives -indeed the first one- was to
increase production. However, that increase went too far and caused a great burden on the
budget.
c) The system was intended to favor small, low
income farmers, but it did just the opposite in practice. Everything was set in such a
fashion that more production brought more gains, and the ones who could produce more were
the big farmers, not the smaller ones. Besides, per capita income of the farmers raised in
nominal values, but in proportion to the society as a whole, it remained more or less the
same. d) Mechanism of price
fixing was done by political decisions, rather than supply and demand conditions. e) The evergrowing
production became a great burden on the intervention mechanisms. That financial burden of
guarantee buyings and subsidies were in fact on the taxpayers, which created a very unjust
situation. In addition, the resources of the Community were running low, and a solution
was needed to stop that in order not to go bankrupt. f) Export subsidies
and import restrictions were causing great resentment of the third countries, and they
were putting pressure on the EC to leave these protectionist measures. g) The more efficient
ways of production with the aid of chemicals and other technological improvements were
harming the environment. h) The green rate
system, which is a special exchange rate employed for agricultural products in converting
ECU prices to national prices, tended to harm
the efforts of creating a common monetary system. All of these conflicts
and problems grew bigger in the 1970's and 1980's, making reforms inevitable. C. 1970’s and 1980's: Reforms of 1970's were
largely aimed at structural improvements, while there are also some efforts to curb the
overproduction tendency. These included modernizing of the farms, offering farmers lump
sums in return for leaving the land, training them to raise the income earning potential,
assisting farmers in mountainous and remote areas and some structural improvements at the
processing and marketing systems. In the 1980's, more
serious reforms were adopted to limit the production, because the policy could no longer
be maintained as its current form. The idea of 1980's was improvement of incomes by cost
reductions rather than output increases and assistance for structural improvement aimed at
low income farmers. In 1984, the open
ended system was abolished, with the quota put on milk. This meant that when the surplus
product exceeds a certain level, there will not be any intervention to buy up that
surplus. Later on, quotas were also adopted for the beef sector. These quotas were
successful to some extent, but they did not help the budget from running out of funds. So,
the Community started to seek a solution. Proposals were based on two major ideas: 1. Set aside
system: This meant
compensation to farmers for taking land out of surplus production, and it was favored by
Germany. 2. Stabilizers: This was an output
threshold, beyond which price cuts would be introduced as a deterrent. This was tried for
milk and became successful. It was a measure especially backed by Great Britain, but this
had a problem of deciding on the threshold. In 1988 Brussels
Summit, it was decided to give the main emphasis on stabilizers, while providing set aside
measures at the same time. Prize freezes and cuts for cereals and vegetables were
introduced, together with a similar penalty system for oilseeds.
D. 1990’s: In the 1990's,
external pressure was more strongly felt to leave agricultural protection measures. An
example is the Uruguay Round of GATT, starting in 1986 and concluding in 1993, where EC
was put into great pressure from the Cairns group, backed by the USA. They demanded a 90 %
cut in EC farm export subsidies and a 75 % cut in other agricultural supports. In
response, Community agreed a 30 % reduction over an extended period. What shaped the
reforms of 1990's is a reform package called the "Mac Sharry Proposals" or "Mac Sharry
Reforms". This was the most radical attempt to return the CAP to a situation
of balance, with the aim of breaking the linkage between the reward to farmers and their
production. It was a fairly comprehensive system of proposals, including sections on
environment and suggestions for re-afforestation. But the most important part of it is the
measures for major products, namely cereals, milk and beef, which cover approximately 75 %
of all production. In cereals, a 35 %
target price reduction was offered in an extended period of three years, counterbalanced
with compensation for small farmers who would suffer income losses and for set aside.
Similar proposals were made also for oilseeds and other proteins. In the milk sector, an
extension of the existing quota system was introduced, together with reduction in prices.
Its counterpart would be compensation for farmers who volunteer to cease production. The mechanism for the
beef sector was a reduction in the intervention price, which is to be reduced by 15 %,
again in an extended period of three years. As in the case of cereals, compensation
payments were offered to farmers who will suffer income losses. The mechanism for
sheepmeat sector was somewhat different. Here, the aim was to reduce the size of flocks. Besides these specific
measures, generally the report offered more environmental friendly types of farming (i.e.
less use of pesticides and fertilizers), and early retirement schemes for farmers, with EU
financement. These reforms had been
successful in some areas, especially the cereal sector, but it is not easy to say anything
about the future effects of them. III. FUTURE OF THE CAP: Future plans of the CAP are in
general further cuts in support prices, compensations continuing via direct payments and
more comprehensive use of social and cohesion funds; with more autonomy to national
governments, as stated in the Agenda 2000 proposals of 1997, which contain a section on
agricultural regulations. Following paragraph is a quotation from the "Agenda 2000:
The Legislative Proposals" page of the web site of EU: " All the
agricultural proposals are due to come into effect in the year 2000.....As indicated in
Agenda 2000, the further reductions in market support prices proposed and the increase in
direct payments to farmers are designed to improve the competitiveness of the EU on
domestic and world markets, thus reducing the risk of a return to the production of
expensive and unsaleable surpluses while avoiding over compensation. Part of the
reinforced direct payments will take the form of a financial envelope which member states
can distribute, subject to certain criteria, thereby allowing member states to address
their specific priorities......Moreover, there will be increased emphasis in the new CAP
on food safety and environmental concerns......."[5] PART 2 I. RELATIONS OF TURKISH AGRICULTURE
AND THE EU:
Ankara Agreement: Relations of Turkish agricultural
sector and the EU dates back to the 1960's, with the first important formal agreement with
the EC, the Ankara Agreement of 1963. According
to Article 11 of the Ankara Agreement, the
association regime set forth by the said agreement includes the exports and imports of the
agricultural products as well, with special consideration to the Common Agricultural
Policy of the Community.[6] In this framework, the Community gave
concessions to some of Turkish agricultural exports with a transitional protocol added to
the agreement and with the Association
Council decisions.[7] These concessions included tariff
quotas, some reductions in the customs duties and some other financial facilities.
According to the Article 2 of the Transitional Protocol, EC opened tariff quotas for four
traditional agricultural products, namely, tobacco, hazelnuts, dried figs and raisins.
These quotas were not fully used in 1964, because of limited time, for the agreement came
into power by December of 1964.[8] In 1966, Turkey applied for an
increase in these quotas, with reference to the Article 4 of the Transitional Protocol,
which states that the tariff quotas can be increased by the Association Council from the
second year of the agreement's coming into power. That application was accepted, and the
quotas for these products (except for hazelnuts) were increased by 10 to 15 %.[9] With reference again to the
Transitional Protocol (Art. 6 stated that in the third year of the agreement, Association
Council can decide on Turkey's entrance to the Common Market with new products.), Turkey
applied for new quotas for some sea products, which included mackerel, tuna fish, crabs,
shrimps, lobsters, octopus and other sea fish. However, this regime was to be applied until the common fisheries policy of the Community
came into force.[10] With regard to the citrus fruits,
a 20 % customs duty reduction was decided, with a limitation of 10.000 tons. If the
exports exceed that amount, the Community has the right to take some measures. These
regulations on citrus fruits were to be applied until a general regime on Mediterranean
products came into force. There were also some quotas for quality wines and grapes coming
from Turkey.[11] It can be concluded that these
regulations had a positive impact on
Additional Protocol: The Additional Protocol that came
into force in January 1973 kept agricultural products out of Customs Union, and
anticipated that Turkish agricultural policy to be harmonized with CAP of EU in a 22 years
term; in order to reach a free circulation of agricultural products. That free circulation
was not going to be automatically reached, however; but depend on the decisions of the
Association Council.[13] Within this framework, EC gave
some new concessions to Turkey, which can be examined in five main categories:[14] 1)Products that have a zero
customs tariff according to the preferential treatment to Turkey: These constitute of raisins,
tobacco, figs, dried vegetables, etc.; which make up of 36.6 % of the 1973 agricultural
export to the EEC-9. 2) Products that enjoy a partial
preference: These products constituted 26.8 %
of the 1973 agricultural export to the EEC-9 and enjoyed a certain discount on the common
external tariff. These were products like non refined olive oil, hazelnuts (the amount
remaining within the quota), citrus fruits, etc. 3) Products that did not enjoy any
preferential treatment: These constituted of 22.8 % of our
agricultural export to EEC-9 in 1973. In this category there were important export goods
like hazelnuts (which remain outside of the quota), refined olive oil and tomato paste. 4) Products with a zero Common
External Tariff: These were products like cotton[15] or bagasse, and they made up of 9.8 %
of the agricultural exports to EEC-9 in 1973. There was already no common external tariff
applied to these products, so the agreement did not make a difference. 5) Non-classifieds: These small amount of
non-classified materials constituted of 3.7 % of our agricultural exports to EEC-9.[16] As a result, these concessions
made a difference for about 63.4 % of our 1973 agricultural exports to EEC-9. (Categories
1 and 2 taken together.) To make a comparison on the importance of these concessions given
by the Additional Protocol, the Lome Convention of 1975 can be taken into consideration,
in which the Asian Pacific and Carribean countries were given a right of entrance without
any customs duties for 96 % of their agricultural exports.[17] Moreover, the fact that similar
concessions are given to other Mediterranean countries after their entrance to the EC
undermined our "preferred" position, for these were our rivals in our most
important products such as raisins and citrus fruits. With the association Council
decision of 1980, an automatic system was introduced in the customs duty reductions, and
it was agreed that these customs were to be abolished on a gradual basis until 1987;
except for regulations according to calendar for some fresh fruits and vegetables, quota
limitations for hazelnut and apricot pulp and a principle of auto-limitation for tomato
paste.[18] However,
it should be noted that these gradual elimination of customs did not mean the elimination
of non-tariff barriers such as reference prices, minimum import prices, import calendars
(In certain periods, common external tariff was applied against agricultural products
coming from the third countries as a protective measure for community producers.), changable customs duties, etc. Our exemption from
the customs duties was limited to an "ad valorem" basis. Besides, some of our
products has been rejected with the claim that they do not fit the health standards of EC,
like potatoes or horse meat.[19] When it comes to Turkey's
obligations, it can be said that they are more loosely defined. According to the Annex 6
of the Additional Protocol, Turkey has to apply a preferential regime in order to increase
imports from the EC countries. Within this framework, Turkey started a preference margin
in terms of taxation in the Import Regime of 1993, which is to be enlarged with the Import
Regime of 1994.[20]
Harmonization Efforts of Turkey: Turkey had further the obligation
to harmonize her agricultural policy with CAP, according to the Article 33 of Additional
Protocol. With the Association Council decision of 1980, an Ad Hoc Agricultural Committee
was established to work towards this aim, however it could not perform its task because of
several reasons.[21] In 1989, a memorandum was given
to the Association Council to demand cooperation in the pilot sectors of cereals and fresh
fruits and vegetables, but an answer could not be reached. An effort started in 1992 to
create alternative policies for import-export balance in agricultural products. This was a
system similar to CAP, with measures like
guarantee buyings and target prices, etc. This system was adopted first for cotton in 1992
and then for tobacco in 1993.[22] In the area of standards regarding
animal and plant health, new regulations were adopted in fisheries and animal products.
However, there are still obstacles in our exports to some member states in this area.[23] Other areas in need of further
harmonization efforts are quality standards and health regulations in processed
agricultural products, like tomato paste; and protection of consumer rights, which will be
mentioned again in this paper.
Developments after the Customs Union: After Turkey entered the Customs
Union in 1995, there has not been so many differences in agricultural relations with the
EU, for agriculture was not included in the relevant treaty. This quotation from a
document of the Ministry of Foreign Affairs of Turkey entitled "The Customs Union
Between Turkey and the European Union" states that:
"...Although
agricultural products are excluded from the treaty, Turkey is progressively adopting many
aspects of the Common Agricultural Policy. The EU will take as much account as possible of
Turkish agricultural interests when developing its agricultural policy. Progressive
improvement, on a mutually advantageous basis, of the preferential arrangements for the
trade in agricultural products is also envisaged...." [24]
According to the
Association Council decisions of 25th February 1998, quantitative restrictions and equal
measures on imports and exports were prohibited, and two categories were created for
agricultural products: first category was exempt from ad valorem duties, while for the
products in the second category reductions and elimination of ad valorem duties was during
a period and subject to certain conditions. There was also a cooperation scheme envisaged
in the Article 4 of the same document.[25] II.
COMPARISON OF TURKISH AGRICULTURE WITH EU:
Agricultural Land:
Total
agricultural land in Turkey is 27,5 million hectares in 1986 numbers. This number is about
80 million hectares in EU, excluding pastures, for the same year. (That numbers are 49,1
million hectares and 129 million hectares respectively, when the pastures are added.) One
problem about the productive use of agricultural land has been the practice of fallowing
in Turkey. The amount of land left to fallow has been reduced, however, from 33,2 % of the
total agricultural land in 1958 to 21 % in 1986, and attempts to reduce it further are
continuing. A different problem in EU is the practice of leaving aside land because of
overproduction.[26]
Productivity:
Agricultural
productivity is lower than EU in Turkey. This difference was greater in 1970's, but Turkey
showed improvement especially on some important products like tobacco or citrus fruits.[27] However, The EU countries showed a
greater improvement during these years, mostly due to effects of CAP.
Structure of Agricultural Production:
Weight of
agricultural production is on plants and especially on cereals in Turkey, while it is on
animal products such as dairy products and beef in the EU countries. In 1986, 50 % of total agricultural land was used
for cereal production in Turkey. This number was 28 % for EU countries for the same year.[28]
Support for Producers:
The producers of
EU countries has been supported and protected by the means of CAP from 1966 onwards. That
policy of support caused overproduction and the EU countries tried to curb that tendency
since 1970-1980's.
In Turkey,
agricultural support mechanisms has always been criticized for not being efficient.
Support for the producers were done by two means: "direct support", as in the
form of financial aids to farmers or support for products; and "indirect
support", as in the form of efforts to increase productivity, investment on
infrastructure, etc. An important component of support for agriculture is the various
cooperatives for producers in Turkey. Financial sources of support to producers are
generally some funds set for this aid, Bank of Agriculture (Ziraat Bankasi), and state
budget. An important problem about support buyings is that support does not go to the
agricultural sector, but rather to some intermediary organizations. That is the most
criticized point in direct support mechanisms.[29]
Protection of Consumers:
The EU has
accepted it as a principal to protect the consumers within CAP. Difference between
intervention prices and "social prices" for beef can be an example of that in
practice. It is on average three times cheaper for consumer than the intervention price.
(143 ECU per 100 kg. against 413.20 ECU per 100 kg in Belgium; 149.5 to 437.5 in France;
143 to 447.6 in Greece and 157.4 to 460.9 in Italy.)[30] This
kind of applications are usually employed in cereals and animal products.[31]
In Turkey,
protection of consumers is the responsibility of the state according to the constitution.
However, this duty was not realized properly. Recently, a law on the protection of
consumers is passed (enacted by the March of 1995), and some civil associations with this
aim are founded. These efforts seem to be made mostly because of harmonization concerns
with the CAP.
Health Standards:
Difference in
health standards between Turkey and the EU countries sometimes become an obstacle on our
exports to the EU countries. An example of this is the agricultural chemicals residual
case. Some of our exports are refused by the importing countries for the amount of
agricultural chemical residuals exceed the maximum value set by their standards. Another
example of obstacles is the agricultural quarantine, which is applied to Turkish potatoes
with the claim of carrying a certain plant disease.[32]
Agricultural Workforce:
With the effect
of CAP on productivity, agricultural population decreased by 35 % between 1973 and 1982,
while the agricultural production increased by 18 %.[33]
In Turkey, agricultural
population also decreased, from 77,4 % of the total workforce in 1955 to 52,1 % of the
total workforce in 1990. By the 1990 numbers, around 11.5 million people work in
agriculture.[34] In 1993, the percentage of agriculture
and forestry in total workforce has been 44.5 % and in 1997 it has been 41.9 %.[35] III. COMPETENCY OF TURKISH PRODUCTS ON EU
MARKETS:
In this part, chances of export to the
EU markets of Turkish agricultural products
are examined sector by sector.
1. Cereals:
EU has reached a self sufficiency level of 138.3 % in
cereals by 1986. In general, Turkey does not seem to have a chance in exporting wheat to
the Union; for she is in serious need of these cereals herself, mostly because of
nutrition traditions in the country. The only chance can be in maize or rice, depending on
our level of self sufficiency in these products.[36]
2. Legimunous Plants: EU
has a self sufficiency level of 75 % in legimunous plants by 1986, but it still buys about half of the world import in that area. Turkey is
an exporter country in legimunous plants, and our chances depend on increasing of our
production.[37]
3. Cotton: Cotton is produced in Greece and
Spain within the EU, and production level is below the need. It is supported by the
measures of CAP[38], but the EU is still a cotton
importer. Cotton is used for textile and oil industries in Turkey, and also exported
abroad. In this area, we may have a serious chance in EU markets.[39]
4. Tobacco: In terms of tobacco, EU is a
major buyer in the world, importing about 35 % of the world production. Tobacco is
produced in Belgium, Germany, Spain, Portugal, Italy and Greece in the EU. However,
Oriental type tobacco, which is a higher quality tobacco than Virginia or Burley type is
only produced in Greece and Italy. (Greece produces 69 % of Oriental type tobacco in the
EU.) Turkey may have a chance of increasing her tobacco exports to EU, for it is a major
producer of Oriental type tobacco.[40]
5. Sugarbeet: Turkey is nearly self sufficient in sugarbeet
production, thanks to modern techniques in production. However, EU is ahead us in terms of
productivity in this area and it has a self sufficiency level of 135 % by 1986-1987. So,
we do not seem to have any chance in sugar exports to EU.[41]
6. Potatoes, Onion and Garlic: In terms of these plants, Turkey is above the self
sufficiency level. The same is true for EU, especially after the membership of Spain. We
may have a chance of export if we can produce potatoes earlier than the normal time, but
we also have rivals like Egypt, Cyprus, Morocco Israel, Malta and other North African
countries in early potato production.[42]
7. Oilseeds: Both Turkey and the EU is
below the self sufficiency level in terms of oilseeds, and both import from outside to
meet the domestic demand. It is not possible to export oilseeds before Turkey increases
production and becomes self sufficient. Besides, olive oil is an especially sensitive
issue for Mediterranean countries, so it may be better to turn to the third countries for
olive oil export.[43]
8. Fresh Vegetables: Although EU is self
sufficient in that respect, it still imports from outside. It considers the period between
October and April as "out of season", and gives more weight to imports from
third countries in this period. It is possible to enter the market with advantage if
Turkey can produce fresh vegetables 10-15 days earlier than the usual time.[44]
9. Tea: EU meets its need totally with
import from third countries, since tea is not grown in the EU. Turkey is one of the major
tea producers in the world, after some countries like China, India and Sri-Lanka, and in
that area we have a greater market chance with proper processing and packaging.[45]
10. Fresh Fruits: Turkey is generally self
sufficient in terms of fruit, and she produces surplus in some fruit types. The self
sufficiency of EU in fresh fruits is around 88 %, while
this number is around 76 % in citrus fruits. Net demand deficiency of EU in
citrus fruits is in grapefruits. "Turkish citrus production takes the 13th place
among the world countries, while this figure is 5 among the Mediterranean countries."[46] Turkey has a rather high potential of
export in terms of citrus fruits.[47] The chances of export can be in
grapefruits, and in tropical fruits like kiwi and avocado in case Turkey increases
production in these products.[48]
11. Dried Fruits and Nuts: This category
consists of dried figs, raisins, hazelnuts, nuts, pistachios, and almonds. EU has a self
sufficiency of around 53 % in dried fruits, and this figure is around 65.7 % in various "nuts" (i.e. fruits with a
hard shell). Turkey is more than self sufficient in all of these products and is indeed
dominant in EU markets as well as world markets in raisins, figs and hazelnuts. Increasing
exports to EU in this field depends on increases in pistachio, nut and almond production.[49]
12. Animal Products: In terms of animal
based products such as dairy products, beef or sheepmeat, EU has an overproduction problem
because of reasons discussed in the first part of the paper. Turkey is in the position of
being a market in this field, for it is less than self sufficient, because of low
productivity and some wrong policies followed in recent years in the animal sector. IV. EFFECTS OF TURKEY'S MEMBERSHIP:
Possible Effects on the EU:
If Turkey is
accepted as a full member of the EU, it might have some dramatic effects on the EU, for
this would mean a 22 % of increase in the usable agricultural area, 41 % of increase in
the number of farms and an increase of nearly 50 % in the agricultural workforce. Turkey
is mostly self sufficient agriculturally, and its output has a rather wide range, covering both northern and
Mediterranean products. A large portion of this output is vegetables and vegetables are
not an important product of support under the CAP, while Turkey is not a major producer of
heavily supported products like beef or dairies. This might imply that cost of accepting
Turkey would not be very high. Furthermore, most important Turkish export products, i.e.
figs, raisins, hazelnuts, oriental tobacco and cotton, are not in a position to compete
with most of the member states.[50]
However, it is
not clear what the outcomes may be, when the Turkish producers are given more incentives
to produce like price guarantees and other kinds of supportive CAP measures. There can be
a sharp increase in production levels, especially in cereal sector. Moreover, the guidance
costs to modernize Turkish agriculture may cost a lot to the guidance section of the
EAGGF.[51]
Possible Effects on Turkey:[52]
One problem with
the CAP is the fact that it is a discriminatory policy, supporting some products more than
others. This may have bad effects on Eastern Anatolian producers, who are already in a
worse position than the Western Anatolian producers; while the latter are more likely to
be supported by the CAP.
A second problem
is that it will cause an increase in the prices given to producers and this will be
reflected in the consumer prices. Increased food prices will effect poorer sections of the
society more seriously, and this may deepen the problem of income distribution.
Moreover,
increased food prices will lead to higher wages and an increase in the already high
inflation. This would also have an effect of undermining the Turkey's low labor cost
advantage. CONCLUSION:
Agriculture is a difficult sector to
plan, and CAP has always been a very problematic policy area for the EU. With the 1992
reforms and proposals for 2000, it can be said that CAP is now a more logical policy.
However, it is still costly, because money is also needed for reform programs, and there
is also the problem of the newcomers, which will make new adjustments inevitable, for
theses are major agricultural producers. Measures must be taken not to encourage any
increase in agricultural production anymore, and to discourage fraud and abuse of the
system of financial compensation. In general, it seems that further reforms of CAP is
indispensable, as the conditions of the world and EU change. Success of the CAP will
depend on its ability to adjust the new conditions. The EU is
one of the most important trading partners of Turkey. In the year 1997, 54 % of Turkey's
total imports came from the EU-15, and 44,4 % of its total exports were sold to the EU-15.[53] When we evaluate the willingness of Turkey in becoming a full member of the EU in the light of all the information provided in this paper, it seems that the costs of the absorption of Turkish agriculture into the CAP may be higher than presumed for both sides. There are even claims that budgetary impact of the Turkey's membership would be greater than that of Greece, Spain and Portugal combined.[54] So, it does not seem possible to hope that the EU will welcome us in our present situation. Moreover, there are also certain costs for Turkey as well, and what the membership to EU will bring and what it will cost should be well calculated before pressing for full membership. Books: · Afanasiev, L. and
Kolovnyakov, V., 1976, Contradictions of Agrarian Integration in the Common Market, Moscow, Progress Publishers · Avillez, Francisco,
1993, "Portugese Agriculture and the Common Agricultural Policy", Portugal
and EC Membership Evaluated, ed. by Jose Da Silva Lopes, London, Pinter Publishers, Chapter 2. · Coffey, Peter, 1996, Europe-Toward
2001, International studies in Economics and Econometrics, vol. 35, Netherlands,
Kluwer Academic Publishers · Doğruel, Fatma (Doç.
Dr.), 1993, Tarım Destekleme Politikaları ve Sonuçları: ABD, AT ve Türkiye,
İstanbul, İstanbul Ticaret Odası · Gökdere,
Ahmet (Doç. Dr.), 1989, Gümrük Birliği Açısından Avrupa Topluluğu ve Türkiye
ile İlişkileri, Ankara, Ankara Üniversitesi Avrupa Topluluğu Araştırma ve
Uygulama Merkezi Araştırma Dizisi Yayın No:2. · Gürakan,
Tulu et.al., 1993, Topluluğun Tarım Ürünlerindeki Ortak Piyasa Düzenleri, Fiyat
Politikaları ve Destekleme Sistemleri, Araştırma-İnceleme Dizisi, Ankara, Hazine
ve Dışticaret Müsteşarlığı Matbaası · Harrison, D. M., 1995, The
Organisation of Europe: Developing a Continental Market Order, London, Routledge · İktisadi Kalkınma
Vakfı, 1974, Avrupa Ekonomik Topluluğu Türkiye İlişkileri Açısından Türk Tarımının
Sorunları (Seminer, 25-26 Nisan 1974), İstanbul, İktisadi Kalkınma Vakfı
Yayınları. · Karabağlı, Aslan,
1989, Avrupa Topluluğu (AT) ve Türkiye Tarımının Verimlilik Pazarlama ve Dış
Ticaret Açısından Değerlendirilmesi, Ankara, Milli Prodüktivite Merkezi Yayınları. · Milli Prodüktivite
Merkezi Tarım Şubesi, n.d., AET Tarım Politikaları Karşısında Türkiye Tarımı
ve MPM'nin Rolü, Ankara, Milli Prodüktivite Merkezi Yayınları: 55. · Molle, William, 1990, The
Economics of European Integration: Theory, Practice, Policy, GB, Dortmouth · Redmond, John, 1993, The
Next Mediterranean Enlargement of the European Community: Turkey, Cyprus and Malta,
England, Dortmouth Publishing Co. · Swann, Dennis, 1995, The
Economics of the Common Market: Integration in the European Union (8th edition),
England, Penguin Books · Şahinöz,
Ahmet (Doç. Dr.), 1989, AET-Türkiye Tarım Politikaları ve Dünya Pazarları
(Ortadoğu), İstanbul, Türkiye Sınai Kalkınma Bankası Ekonomik Analiz Konjünktür
ve Sektör İzleme Müdürlüğü. · Yedinci
Beş Yıllık Kalkınma Planı Özel İhtisas Komisyonu Raporu, 1995, Tarımda Yapısal
Uyum, Destekleme ve Uluslararası Piyasalara Entegrasyon, Ankara, TC Başbakanlık
Devlet Planlama Teşkilatı Müsteşarlığı Yayın No: DPT: 2409-ÖİK: 470 Articles: · Bedestenci,
Ali Kemal, 1990, "Türkiye-AT Tarım İlişkileri", Tarım Orman Köy,
Mart 1990, 49, pp. 44-45. · Hızal,
Yılmaz, 1989, "Avrupa Topluluğu (AT), Komşu ve Yakın Doğu Ülkelerine Turunçgil
İhracı, Ekonomik Önemi ve Bunların Geliştirilmesi", Tarım Orman Köy,
Kasım 1989, 45, pp.10-11. · Runge, Carlisle Ford,
1988, "The Assault on Agricultural Protectionism", Foreign Affairs 67
(1), Fall 1988, 133-150 · Uludağ, Necati, 1989, Türkiye
Turunçgil Tarımının Dünyadaki Yeri, Tarım Orman Köy, Mart 1990, 45, pp.6-7. Web Sites: · http://www.europa.eu.int · http://www.die.gov.tr · http://www.mfa.gov.tr [1] Harrison, D.M., The Organisation of Europe: Developing A Continental Market Order, Routledge London, 1995, p.129 [2] ibid., p.130 [3] Molle, William, The Economics of European Integration: Theory, Practice, Policy, Dortmouth, GB, 1990, p.251 [4] ibid., p.251 [5] http://www.europa.eu.int [6]Yedinci Bes Yillik Kalkinma Plani Özel Ihtisas Komisyonu Raporu, Tarimda Yapisal Uyum, Destekleme ve Uluslararasi Piyasalara Entegrasyon, DPT Yayin No:2409, Ankara, 1995, p.50. [7]ibid., p.50. [8]MPM Tarim Subesi, AET Tarim Politikalri Karsisinda Turkiye Tarimi ve MPM'nin Rolu, MPM Merkezi Yayinlari:55, Ankara, n.d., p.194. [9]ibid., p.247. [10]ibid., pp.252-253. [11]ibid., pp.253-254. [12]Iktisadi Kalkinma Vakfi Yayinlari, Avrupa Ekonomik Toplulugu Turkiye Iliskileri Acisindan Turk Tariminin Sorunlari, Istanbul, 1974, pp.213-214. [13]Ali Kemal Bedestenci, "Türkiye-AT Tarim Iliskileri", Tarim Orman Koy, Mart 1990, 49, p.44. [14]Doc. Dr.
Ahmet Gökdere, Gümrük Birligi Açisindan Avrupa
Toplulugu ve Türkiye ile Iliskileri, AU Avrupa [15]This was the situation before cotton producing countries (such as Greece) entered the EC. [16]ibid., pp.166-167. [17]ibid., p.167. [18]Yedinci Bes Yillik Kalkinma Plani Özel Ihtisas Komisyonu Raporu, Tarimda Yapisal Uyum, Destekleme ve Uluslararasi Piyasalara Entegrasyon, DPT Yayin No:2409, Ankara, 1995, p.51. [19]Ali Kemal Bedestenci, "Türkiye-AT Tarim Iliskileri", Tarim Orman Koy, Mart 1990, 49, p.45. [20]Yedinci Bes Yillik Kalkinma Plani Özel Ihtisas Komisyonu Raporu, Tarimda Yapisal Uyum, Destekleme ve Uluslararasi Piyasalara Entegrasyon, DPT Yayin No:2409, Ankara, 1995, p.51-52. [21]Ali Kemal Bedestenci, "Türkiye-AT Tarim Iliskileri", Tarim Orman Koy, Mart 1990, 49, p.44. [22]ibid., p.52. [23]ibid., p.53. [24]Quoted from the web site of the Ministry of Foreign Affairs: http://www.mfa.gov.tr. [25]From the web site of the European Union: http://www.europa.eu.int. [26]Arslan Karabagli, Avrupa Toplulugu (AT) Tarimi ve Turkiye Tariminda Verimlilik Pazarlama ve Dis Ticaret Açisindan Degerlendirilmesi, MPM Yayin No:383, Ankara, 1989, p.52-53. [27]ibid., pp.57-58. [28]ibid., pp.54-56. [29]Doç.Dr.Fatma Dogruel, 1993, Tarim Destekleme Politikalari ve Sonuclari: ABD, AT ve Turkiye, pp.49-72. [30]Arslan Karabagli, Avrupa Toplulugu (AT) Tarimi ve Turkiye Tariminda Verimlilik Pazarlama ve Dis Ticaret Açisindan Degerlendirilmesi, MPM Yayin No:383, Ankara, 1989, p.69, Table 12. [31]Arslan Karabagli, Avrupa Toplulugu (AT) Tarimi ve Turkiye Tariminda Verimlilik Pazarlama ve Dis Ticaret Açisindan Degerlendirilmesi, MPM Yayin No:383, Ankara, 1989, p.68-69. [32]ibid., pp.119-123. [33]Doç.Dr.Fatma Dogruel, Tarim Destekleme Politikalari ve Sonuclari: ABD, AT ve Turkiye, ITO Yayin No:1993-29, Istanbul, 1993, p.28. [34]Data taken from the web site of DIE: http://www.die.gov.tr. [35]Data taken from the web site of the EU: http://www.europa.eu.int. [36][36]Arslan Karabagli, Avrupa Toplulugu (AT) Tarimi ve Turkiye Tariminda Verimlilik Pazarlama ve Dis Ticaret Açisindan Degerlendirilmesi, MPM Yayin No:383, Ankara, 1989, pp.128-129. [37]ibid., p.129. [38]Dr. Tulu Gürakan, et.al., Toplulugun Tarim Urunlerindeki Ortak Piyasa Duzenleri, Fiyat Politikalari ve Destekleme Sistemleri, HDTM, Ankara, 1993, p.61. [39]Arslan Karabagli, Avrupa Toplulugu (AT) Tarimi ve Turkiye Tariminda Verimlilik Pazarlama ve Dis Ticaret Açisindan Degerlendirilmesi,MPM Yayin No:383, Ankara, 1989, pp.130-131. [40]ibid., pp.131-132. [41]ibid., p.132. [42]ibid., p.132. [43]ibid., pp.132-133. [44]ibid., pp.133-134. [45]ibid., pp.134-135. [46]Necati Uludag, "The Role of Turkish Citrus Production in the World", Tarim Orman Koy, Kasim 1989, s. 45, p.6. [47]Dr. A. Yilmaz Hizal, "Turkish Citrus Exports to EC and Near East Countries, Its Economic Importance and Development", Tarim Orman Koy, Kasim 1989, s. 45, p.11. [48]Arslan Karabagli, Avrupa Toplulugu (AT) Tarimi ve Turkiye Tariminda Verimlilik Pazarlama ve Dis Ticaret Açisindan Degerlendirilmesi, MPM Yayinlari:383, Ankara, 1989, pp.135-136. [49]ibid., pp.136-137. [50]John Redmond, The Next Mediterranean Enlargement of the European Community: Turkey, Cyprus and Malta, Dortmouth Publishing Co., England, 1993, pp. 34-35. [51]ibid., p.35. [52]ibid., pp.35-36. [53]Data taken from the web site of the EU: http://www.europa.eu.int [54]John Redmond, The Next Mediterranean Enlargement of the European Community: Turkey, Cyprus and Malta, Dortmouth Publishing Co., England, 1993, p.39.
|
Yıldız Teknik Üniversitesi İktisadi ve İdari Bilimler Fakültesi Siyaset Bilimi ve Uluslararası İlişkiler Bölümü Yüksek Lisans Öğrencileri Tarafından Hazırlanmaktadır. Tel: 0 212 327 07 20 0 212 259 70 70 / 2683 E'posta: fuataksu@ixir.com
|